Apologies in advance for this very long thread, but as regular readers know, I worry greatly about common misunderstandings of the role of reserve currencies. The author seems to assume that what makes a currency a dominant reserve currency is...
its low frictional trading costs, which is why, he believes, digital currencies, with China in the lead, will dominate international trade.
But while a low frictional trading cost is a necessary condition, it is not nearly sufficient. A quick glance at the role of the...
3/19
US dollar over the past 100 years, the period during which it achieved dominant status, makes this clear: when the world was short of savings relative to its investment needs, during the first fifty years of that period (a period characterized by the global need to...
4/19
rebuild economically from 2 world wars) the US was a permanent net provider of savings to the world.
In the next five decades, however, when the global economy was substantially rebuilt and needed to export excess savings, the US automatically became a permanent net...
5/19
absorber of foreign savings. Of course during this time the US shifted from permanent trade surpluses, when the world needed the US to supply it with food, capital goods and consumer goods, to permanent trade deficits, when the world urgently some place in which to dump...
6/19
excess production of consumer goods.
This was no mere coincidence. To me it suggests three things. First, that reserve currency status is a function of a lot more than low-cost trading. In fact given that the cost is already so low, and seems to be in permanent decline...
7/19
decline anyway, I suspect it doesn't even matter much any more.
What seems to matter a lot more is the willingness of the reserve-currency country to run large imbalances in response not to its own needs but rather to the needs of the rest of the world. As an excellent...
8/19
CFR resource shows, the US typically absorbs 40-50% of global imbalances, and the Anglophone economies — with similar financial markets all of whom, like the US, punch way above their weights as international reserve currencies — collectively...
Given that China's currency (and that of other surplus countries, like Japan) punches so far below it's weight, it is surprising that anyone would argue that there is no relationship between the international status of a currency...
10/19
and its willingness and ability to absorb global imbalances.
Second, the reason these countries are "willing" to accept major reserve-currency status has more to do with ideology than with economic rationality, driven by, and reinforcing, the disproportionate power of...
11/19
the financial sector on domestic decision-making. Like the UK in the 1920s, they are perhaps too willing to sacrifice the needs of the producer side of their economies in order to maintain the overwhelming power of the financial side. The result, as Matthew Klein and I...
12/19
show in our book, is that these reserve-currency countries have constantly to choose between allowing unemployment to rise or allowing debt to rise. They have mostly chosen the latter.
And third, while China has been promising for nearly two decades that its currency will achieve dominant reserve status within five years or so, in fact the RMB is probably the least important of the top ten currencies given China's status as the second largest economy...
14/19
and largest trader in the world, and by relevant standards its role has barely improved in the past decade and may even have declined.
Why? Because for all over-excited talk about achieving major international status, Beijing has always refused to take the economic...
15/19
steps needed to increase its role in absorbing global imbalances.
On the contrary, when Covid-19 created a demand shock in a world already suffering from excess savings and insufficient demand, Beijing had an incredible opportunity to boost the role of the RMB by...
16/19
boosting net domestic demand. Instead it implemented a muscular supply-side response that actually worsened its contribution to global demand imbalances.
In the end I do expect the international status of the US dollar eventually to decline, but not because of the...
17/19
rise of the yen (which, we were told in the 1980s and 1990s, was virtually assured) or of the RMB. Either it will decline because the US decides that it is no longer willing to absorb the huge and rising economic cost of dominant reserve-currency status to its producing...
18/19
sectors and its balance sheet in exchange for the declining geopolitical benefits and to maintain the status and dominance of of its financial sector (which may be the same thing), or it will decline when the cost of maintaining the power of the dollar helps...
19/19
sufficiently undermine the US economy, which has always been the real source of American power. The experience of the UK in the 1920s provides an accelerated vision of how that can happen.
1/2 I did a quick back-of-the-envelope calculation of currency-share to GDP-share of the top ten currencies:
NZD 9.4
HKD 8.9
SFR 6.2
GPB 4.2
Aus dollar 4.4
USD 3.6
Yen 2.9
Can. dollar 2.7
Euro 2.2
RMB 0.3
2/2
There are a lot of problems with this table, not least because it reflects a single point in time, and obviously the smaller the economy, the more likely it is to be an outlier, but it is still interesting.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
1/15
Kenneth Rogoff says: "There is, for example, a terrific chapter in which Ray Dalio brutally critiques Japanese policymakers for failing to force debt writedowns after the country’s early 1990s financial crisis.'
2/15
"Instead," he continues, "they allowed debt overhang to hamstring the financial system and sap two decades of growth."
I haven't read Dalio's book, but this is an extremely important point, and one that Beijing should note.
3/15
Beijing has an enormous of debt that is ostensibly backed by the book value of associated assets (most Chinese debt was used to fund investment), but the economic value of these assets are not worth nearly as much as their book value. ft.com/content/630f82…
1/6 FT: "The value of Chinese exports to Europe in May climbed 12 per cent from a year earlier, with shipments to Germany up 22 per cent. Exports to south-east Asian countries rose 15 per cent."
2/6 The world is already complaining about the disruptions caused by this flood of Chinese exports away from the US to the rest of the world, especially to Europe. But this so far has been the easy part of the global trade adjustment. It will get much worse.
3/6 The Trump administration so far has been unable to bring down the US trade deficit, and as long as the US trade deficit rises, it is much easier for other countries to absorb rising trade deficits with China as these are balanced with rising trade surpluses with the US.
1/7 SCMP: "Hunan has become the first province in China to use the proceeds of special-purpose bonds to guarantee government payments to... scmp.com/economy/china-…
2/7 enterprises, with 20 billion yuan allocated for this year. This marks the first time the bonds – typically earmarked for revenue-generating construction projects – will be used to cover government arrears."
3/7 A large number of local governments have huge amounts of undeclared debt which they cannot service, including arrears to businesses and various complicated forms of triangular deb and cross-debt guarantees.
1/7 This ECB report says that what constrains EU investment is not scarce capital but rather "weakness in demand": "Net responses indicate expectations of near stagnation in euro area business investment over the next three years, but increasing investment outside the...
2/7 outside the euro area, especially in non-EU advanced economies and emerging markets."
I'm sure they're right, but consider what would happen if, as Christine Lagarde and other EU bankers hope, global investors were to begin acquiring EU debt as they shift out of US debt.
3/7 Would these inflows cause EU investment to rise? Not if the constraint for businesses is weak demand for their products. On the contrary, by pushing up the value of the euro, these inflows would probably make European products even less competitive globally.
1/14
This article is a very good illustration of how, in a hyperglobalized world, countries that choose to control their domestic economies—which, among other things, means controlling their capital and trade accounts—can impose... reuters.com/business/finan…
2/14
their domestic imbalances on those of their trade partners that have chosen to accept less control over their capital and trade accounts. In that sense the former absorb (in reverse) the industrial policies of the latter. carnegieendowment.org/china-financia…
3/14
This is what happened in Brazil. It has long been Brazilian policy to reduce the economy's overreliance on commodity production while increasing the role of manufacturing, and for a while it was successful. But in the past two decades, we've seen a major reversal.
1/8 Pan Gongsheng is right to warn of the dangers to the global economy posed by fiscal and regulatory problems in the country issuing the world’s main currency, but the two ways for China to protect itself from running those risks are pretty obvious. nytimes.com/2025/06/18/bus…
2/8 One way would be to rebalance domestic demand by increasing the share of GDP that is directed to China's household sector. In that case China's trade surplus would decline, and China would no longer need to acquire huge amounts of US assets to balance weak domestic demand.
3/8 The other way is for China to balance its weak domestic demand by acquiring assets in countries other than the US. It could instead acquire European and Japanese assets, or it could acquire assets in developing countries, who could then use the inflows to boost investment.