George Selgin Profile picture
Jul 18, 2021 24 tweets 4 min read Read on X
I ended my first thread on Gorton and Zhang's new working paper (papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cf…) by observing (with a nod to work by the late, lamented George Kaufman) that bank runs aren't necessarily a bad thing: papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cf…
That makes for a neat segue to my next criticism, concerning GZ's table 1 (p. 5). Here they consider various "Options to Address Stablecoins," asking of each whether it (1) would eliminate runs on stablecoins and (2) would make it unnecessary for their users to scrutinize them.
Based on those assumed goals, they narrow down acceptable options to three: treatment like ordinary banks, 100% reserve (or Treasurys) backing, or replacement w/ CBDC, that is, outright prohibition.
But should we accept this procedure? If stablecoins are indeed "like" banks, as GZ argue (albeit not consistently), Kaufman's strictures should apply to them. And if they aren't like banks, it's even less clear that they need to be absolutely run-proof.
As Kaufman notes, and as I noted in my previous thread, runs can be an effective means for shutting-down bad banks quickly. They are to be regretted only when they pose systemic risks, because panic spreads like a contagion, or because institutions are "interconnected."
Work by Kaufman himself and by Calomiris and others shows that bank run contagion effects have been much less common and extensive than is often supposed. "Interconnectedness" has been a more common cause of spillovers, but it has rarely been such as posed a systemic thread.
Are stablecoin issuers different? Would a run on one necessarily pose systemic risks? GZ themselves supply an answer 2 pages later, in a footnote where they refer to the sudden, spectacular run on the Iron Titanium Token in June that caused it to become worthless in a single day.
Of course holders of those tokens took a beating, including some who, having first touted it, made their losses a reason to call for more regulation: news.bitcoin.com/mark-cuban-iro…
But economists (usually) look for spillovers before calling for regulation. Where other markets disrupted? Was the run contagious? Did were systemically important Iron Titanium counterparties threatened with failure? Nah.
Instead, some crypto enthusiasts who thought they'd found a way to make a fast buck while others "had fun being poor" got their cumuppance. These weren't people who had no choice but to deal with stablecoins because they had to go shopping: they were investors placing risky bets.
Why should public policy strive to rule-out any chance that such people will incur losses, any more than it strives to ban dealings in penny stocks, gambling, or (and almost certain 100% loss) lottery ticket sales. (Oh, sorry: it has dealt with the last, via GZ's solution # 3!)
If you ask me, the best solution to the "problem" of stablecoins like the Iron Titanium Token is instead GZ's solution 1: do nothing. And by all means don't do anything that suggests that the government is "watching over" them!
What about GZ's 2nd regulatory desideratum, viz., that regulation must help stablecoins achieve "no questions asked" status? Here, the problem is circular reasoning.
GZ maintain that the "no questions asked" (NQA) condition must be met by any decent "money." They then characterize stablecoins as "private money." And so they conclude that regulators must see to it that stablecoins satisfy NQA.
But who, besides GZ, says that stablecoins are or have to be "money"? The standard definition of money is any "generally accepted medium of exchange." No stablecoin today meets that definition. Instead, most are used only for very limited types of transacting.
Tether, for instance, is pretty much used only for cryptocurrency purchases and sales, and then only because most crypto exchanges aren't plugged into the formal, Fed based USD payments network.
Those of us who care only to have some decent "money" to transact with don't bother with stablecoins. Why should we when we already have plenty of NQA alternatives at our disposal? So, who cares if there are non-NQA conforming stablecoins out there?
Perhaps GZ imagine that there is some risk--purely hypothetical at this point--that one or more non-NQA stablecoins will succeed in displacing good-old NQA dollars in ordinary payments. Perhaps they worry that Facebook's Diem will do so.
But for them to suppose so begs the question: if NQA is "the most obvious" property any decent money must have, why would the public abandon established NQA-conforming media for non-NQA alternatives?
If GZ have a reason for thinking it would, they should explain it before they conclude that we need potentially Draconian stablecoin regulations to prevent it. In the meantime, so long as stablecoins aren't _really_ money, they simply don't "need" to be NQA.
That's all for now. Thanks for your attention.
Sheesh! So many typos. Sorry!
Sorry for wrong link. Correct one to Kaufman paper is here: fraser.stlouisfed.org/files/docs/his…
Note: This is not an argument for zero regulation. It is an argument against the assumption that the goal of regulation should be zero stablecoin runs.

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with George Selgin

George Selgin Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @GeorgeSelgin

Feb 25
Free banking failed in the antebellum U.S., despite its remarkable success in Scotland somewhat earlier, for a perfectly simple reason: while Scotland’s banks were for the most part genuinely free, U.S. “free” banks were free in name only. 1/
Despite the “free banking” statutes providing for their establishments, _all_ U.S. “free” were subject to various debilitating regulatory requirements. For one thing, none could branch: instead, all were one-office “unit” banks—small, undiversified, and often undercapitalized. 2/
And all had to back their circulating notes with specific securities chosen by State regulatory authorities. Instead of being especially safe, the chosen securities (including those of the sponsoring governments) often turned out to be junk. 3/
Read 12 tweets
Jan 7
Had I trusted modern textbooks to tell me all I needed to know about my field, instead of reading older classics, I’d never have contributed a thing to it.

Here’s one of dozens of examples.
Those textbooks will all tell you how, in _Lombard Street_ (1873) Walter Bagehot explained that, to avoid financial crises every nation needed a central bank like the Bank of England to serve as a lender-of-last-resort.
Well, if you actually _read_ _Lombard Street_, you will discover that what Bagehot says there is almost the opposite of what textbooks claim: he considered the Bank of England’s monopoly privileges to be the root cause of British financial instability.
Read 8 tweets
Dec 20, 2024
Thread: Conventional wisdom about deposit insurance’s role in U.S. banking history overlooks many important facts.
First, it overlooks how the vast majority of U.S. bank failures during the 20’s and 30’s were if single-location “unit” banks, which, being severely under-diversified, were inherently vulnerable to both sectoral (especially agricultural) and macroeconomic shocks.
Unit banking was an almost uniquely U.S. arrangement—a consequence of state and federal laws that prohibited branch banking within most states, while altogether ruling-out interstate branch networks. So the U.S. entered the depression with >30,000 mostly weak banks.
Read 13 tweets
Dec 16, 2024
An uphead Selgin Bitcoin thread!
Bitcoin's not being, and even never becoming, "money" in most places doesn't mean it can't largely replace fiat. 1/
As recent content on my X feed makes clear, many Bitcoin fans don't like it one bit when I say that throughout most of the world their favorite investment doesn't qualify as "money," defined (as economists have long defined it) as a "generally accepted medium of exchange." 2/
In reply, besides pointing out that I was born before 1964 ('57, to be exact), wishing me good luck being poor, and otherwise insulting me, they have come up with all sorts of other definitions of "money" that allow Bitcoin to qualify. 3/
Read 13 tweets
Dec 13, 2024
File under: Heads We Win; Tails You Lose.
Should the BITCOIN Act providing for a 1-billion coin Strategic Bitcoin Reserve become law, Bitcoin miners and HODLers will certainly benefit. For other Americans, in 20 yrs (the minimum SBR holding period), one of two things can happen.
(1) Bitcoin's price rises by more than 2.5x the gov'ts purchase price. Then IF_the Treasury sells Bitcoin, it can apply any gain to reducing the national debt. Otherwise ordinary taxpayers may not have gained anything.
That "IF" is big for a good reason: the same HODLer and Bitcoin mining lobby that's pushing hard for an SBR would push just as hard to keep the gov't from selling it, much as the gold mining lobby has managed to keep the gov't from clinging to 8,133 metric tons of useless gold.
Read 6 tweets
Dec 13, 2024
File under: Fine print. The BITCOIN Act's Bitcoin purchase plan, which calls for the US gov't to purchase 1 million Bitcoin and hold them for 20 years, could well end up _adding_ to rather than reducing the US government's debt burden.

Allow me to explain. 1/
For the most part, the legislation has the Treasury financing its Bitcoin purchase w/ what amounts to a gold-collaterilized loan from the Federal Reserve System. As the Tsy buys Bitcoin, bank reserves go up; eventually increasing by full amount Fed-financed coin purchase. 2/
Because the Fed must pay interest on those reserves, and earns no interest on its Treasury loan, it loses money on the deal. But as that loss is deducted from the Fed's Treasury remittances, the Tsy ultimately pays, much as it might if it borrowed from the banks directly. 3/
Read 6 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us!

:(