There have been a lot of #notallstablecoin takes flying around from crypto advocates in the last few days. It's worth reiterating a few points from the last time we were going around on this topic.
First, while there are obviously differences between models of stablecoins, and
Specific stablecoins - whether there's a single central issuer, whether it's backed by collateral, what kind of collateral, whether it relies on an algorithmic or actively managed stabilization approach, etc - these differences are all focused on the "backing" side of things.
When it comes to the obligation or liability side, all of these coins are essentially promising the same thing - a fixed or stable nominal price and redemption into a higher form of money/liquidity on demand. Some bury disclaimers in fine print or even quite explicitly say they
Promise no such thing, but those claims are belied by the actual *function* the coins are designed to and do serve, which is to be shadow money in markets/contexts where official monies are either not allowed or dare not go.
What this means is that depending on how you look at
It, different models of stablecoins are either distinct things, or all variations of the same thing - a money promise with *some theory of backing*.
Second, while these backing models are distinct, they share one important feature in common, which is that they are denominated
In a public unit of account and are safe only one the extent the public can (ultimately) exit their position into official money. And in the history of (shadow) banking, there has only been one successful way to consistently ensure that kind of safety: a direct guarantee by the
Monetary authority itself, either through some form of ex ante insurance or ex post bailout.
What this means is that while there may be (are) regulatory and legal changes that would improve the relative safety of, say, custodial stablecoins, or decentralized stablecoins, etc,
Each of those solutions is at best addressing downstream model-specific problems while leaving the biggest, common problem unacknowledged, yet alone resolved.
The real question we should be asking ourselves today is not whether algorithmic stablecoins are uniquely bad - they
Very well may be - but rather whether or not it's worth focusing our energy on addressing those unique bads rather than go to the root of the problem and address it directly, once and for all, across all the entire stablecoin industry.
This was our thinking behind the STABLE Act, drawing inspiration from @MorganRicks1's book, the Money Problem among other sources, and it holds up today.
Because at the end of the day, the problem I described as the "Schrodinger's Coin" problem-that whether or not a particular
Stablecoin's chosen theory of backing is sound or not can only ever be verified at the point where failure means serious consumer harm-remains true. True for Tether, true for Terra, true for USDC and all the others. Banking history is littered with examples of private monies that
Were issued by actors that were convinced this time would be different, that they had cracked the code and would be impervious to systemic risk of failure, etc. Over and over they were proved overly hubristic and it was the public that suffered.
Let this time be the last time.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
This is simply not true. It simply codifies a particular kind of human error (presumption that inelastic currency is pro-social) and chooses not to subject that error to the same degree of political/social scrutiny as governments.
If you start from the political belief that Austrian econ/hard money/sound finance is optimal, then sure, all you're doing is locking in that one political decision and *then* letting people do their thing on top. But that's a big "if"! One I would say the history of democracy is
pretty informative about. But this blindspot toward the implicit collective political value-judgments required for the rest of "market" forces to work as alleged has always been a blindpost of libertarian econ-inspired types.
I'm not a fan of Krugman nor do I have much intrinsic respect for the economics "Nobel Prize", but it was notable in these interactions
just how willing Stewart, who often hid(hides) his politics behind the shield of "i'm just a comedian", was to straight-up dismiss Krugman's arguments, not because he had any substantive response to them, but simply because they stretched credulity beyond what he could grasp.
The Fed's report on CBDCs is out, & predictably, on the most important issue of all - protecting/maintaining cash-like privacy - there is no analysis, just assertion, that anonymity is non-viable b/c greater scale/velocity of digital. Very disappointing.
I've made this point before, but it's important to emphasize: the Fed is not statutorily responsible for issuing cash, nor does its mandate or expertise extend to issues of preserving civil liberties or balancing security/privacy concerns. Its opinions/preferences are not gospel.
Presently and for thousands of years, individuals are/have been able to transact with cash anonymously, and do not need/have not needed to sign-up or provide their identity in order to make transactions with public money. Eliminating that capacity in the digital age is extreme.
@conorsen Plenty of MMTers, including myself, have proposed a) voluntary/mandatory savings programs, b) auto-fiscal stabilizers, c) direct credit regulation (as an alternative form of monetary policy to interest rate hikes). Why are those not sufficient? Believing inflationary risk is real
@conorsen does not require believing traditional approaches to managing inflation risk are good/appropriate.
@conorsen Here's us articulating back in 2019 a range of tools that could/should have been included this past year but weren't, not because MMT had nothing to say but because the Biden admin is not following MMT prescriptions.
1. Prates claims Fed only purchases Tsy securities. But that’s incorrect. The Fed buys both notes & coins from Tsy today, and then sells them onto commercial banks and others, who sell excess coins back to the Fed.
2. The Fed is also legally the Tsy’s fiscal agent, and is required to accept monies deposited by the Tsy. There’s no indication that excludes coins and the law is quite clear if Tsy and Fed disagree on scope of that authority, the law sides with Tsy Sec.
3. Prates argues the Tsy cannot deposit the coin in its regular account because "Fed accounts only receive reserves". But this is a category error, reserves are a *liability* of the Fed. The coin would be an asset, like tsys and other acquired assets.
Easy to dismiss this as a one off, a bad apple, even a sign of the need to tighten up around the edges. But it's deeper, there's a more fundamental legitimacy crisis at play around the technocratic presumptions of central bank dominance and this feeds right into it.
Because reality is that before you can even begin to contemplate the kind of ethics violation that Clarida did, you have to be in a certain economic class where that kind of temptation exists. I dont know many elementary school teachers with investment portfolios like Clarida.