🚨New Paper Alert🚨
Understanding Italy's Stagnation 📉🇮🇹
Today is #Eurogroup. In the €, Italy is a puzzle. 1980s: among highest per-hour GDP. Today: long stagnation & problem child of €Zone. We tried to understand why. Here's what we found. 1/n
First, what's the problem? From 🇩🇪 & 🇪🇺 perspective, debt often foregrounded. Fear of default, too big to fail etc. etc.
True: Italian debt stock among largest in Eurozone (left chart). But the deeper problem is growth (right chart).
2/n
So what happened to growth? Some say: regional story, southern Italy. And the Mezzogiorno did fall behind. But even Italy's fastest-growing region (North east) lagged Italy's European peers. It's a whole-of-Italy story. 3/n
Decomposition shows: Italy lagged 🇩🇪🇫🇷🇪🇸 in both productivity (here defined as GDP-per-hour) and in hours-worked growth. Productivity is main story. But worth briefly looking at hours worked.
4/n
Pre-COVID hours per person employed high (1710 🇮🇹 p.a., vs 1382 in 🇩🇪, 1518 in 🇫🇷), but employment rate low (59% vs 76% 🇩🇪, 66% 🇫🇷). Total hours rose from 1999 (42.2m hrs worked) to 2008 (45.8m), then fell to 43.6m (2019), mostly b/c of more part time, less full time work. 5/n
🚨 Women and the young 😱: 24% of 15-29yr olds not in emplmnt, edction or trning (NEET) in 2019 (OECD avr: 13%). Only 50% of Italian working-age women in employment (OECD avr: 61%). Both are longstanding problems - but not recently worsened. So can't explain declining growth. 6/n
What about productivity? Since 2000, zero overall growth! Strongly lagging in both manufacturing & most services (& negative growth in construction, utilities). The real puzzle.
What's the explanation? I look at three. All provide insights, none of them convinces entirely.
7/n
A) "Italy didn't reform". Often a generic criticism, sometimes specific to labour mkt (excessive protections undermining 🇮🇹 competitiveness etc). Neither is true -- see pp. 15-24 in paper for overview of i) fiscal, ii) labour mkt, iii) competition and iv) political reforms. 8/n
Some relevant data: Brutal fiscal consolidation in 1990s. Italy now highest effective retirement age in 🇪🇺. Wage share & structure of labour mkt transformed, esp. for young & women. Product market regulation (OECD PMR index): 🇮🇹 now more liberal than OECD average and 🇫🇷 🇺🇸🇨🇭9/n
But: reforms often partial. Dualised labour market, insider / outsider problems. Problematic privatisations. Cuts to education spending, esp. universities. Failure to establish either market for corporate control OR effective bank monitoring of firm management. 10/n
B - "It's the €": Italy could no longer devalue, lost competitiveness. Fiscal rules forced austerity.
Some truth, but can't be whole story. If tight fiscal was the problem, why didn't 1998-2005 loosening boost growth? 11/n
And internal devaluation is hard, but why happening (painfully, slowly) in 🇪🇸 but not 🇮🇹?
More promising take: bad reforms undertaken to qualify for & remain in €. 1990s privatisations: desire for quick sales at high valuations. Legacy of extractive firms, low investment. 12/n
C - "firm level perspective": competitiveness, productivity, etc. ultimately happens in firms. So let's look at Italy's firms!
Some striking findings: beyond micro firms (1-9 workers), Italian firms just as productive as French, German, Spanish ones. 13/n
But a) 🇮🇹 micro-firms less productive than 🇩🇪 🇫🇷. b) Composition effect: In all countries, small firms less productive than big ones. Italy has lots more small firms, few large ones. 14/n
And: lots of family-managed firms (= not just family ownership or family CEO, but ENTIRE management structure from owning family/families). Uniquely common in 🇮🇹 (note: chart only covers firms > 10 workers to exclude micro business). Bad for productivity. 15/n
Why are 🇮🇹 firms small & poorly managed? Tough to say. Partly historical, loss of large firms in 1970s. Partly legal system (google "Italian torpedo"), partly corruption (hard to quantify, but it's a thing), partly administration, partly lack of agg demand, partly unclear. 16/n
So, synthesis? Not straightforward. Our best attempt: two decisive historical moments to blame. First: contradictory, counterproductive reform wave of 1990s. Second: retention of bad paradigm after ~2010. 17/n
1990s reform wave: moment of crisis (Mani Pulite, Feb 1992; ERM-exit, Sept 1992). Neoliberal ideas in the air. Plus: never a clear hegemony of reformers (see esp. Berlusconi-led weakening of rule of law, p.43 in paper). Result: contradictory, counterproductive reform mix 👇. 18/n
- Partial labour mkt liberalisation PLUS heavy demand compression: "poor tertiarization", reduced human capital formation (esp. among younger generation), poor incentives for boosting labour productivity, instead creation of low-value add service sector jobs. 19/n
- Contradictory collective bargaining reforms. Centralisation in 1990s: push for greater firm-worker cooperation & LT strategies, towards 🇩🇪-style specialisation. But erosion of employment protection: encouraged short term strategies, 🇬🇧🇺🇸-style generalism. 20/n
- Or corp governance & private finance: privatisation of banking, liberalisation of trading, better minority shareholder protection = encouraged mkt-based monitoring of firm management (via mkt for corporate control). 21/n
But: cntd tolerance of pyramidal & cross-ownership networks plus lifting prohibition for banks to own shares in non-financial firms = more aligned with bank-based monitoring of firms's managers, along pre-1990s German lines. 22/n
Result of 1990s reform mix: low investment, both private (down by 20%, esp. striking in intl. comparison) and public (down by 40% since 1990). Beyond investment numbers: 🇮🇹 missed out on IT revolution & big restructuring of European manufacturing... 23/n
Rise of China + Eastern Europe 🇪🇺-accession => big opportunity, but 🇮🇹 corporates absent. German corps build central European manufacturing core, dense supplier-manufacturer-R&D-sales networks. Core-periphery dynamic now entrenched, mkt investment unlikely to reverse it. 24/n
But: If poor results up to 2008, why retain reform mix after Great Financial Crisis?
External constraint (vincolo esterno) finally bit. 🇮🇹policy makers (rationally) afraid of bond markets. Mkts & mkt-shaping policy makers in Berlin & Brussels still trusted 1990s playbook. 25/n
Econ profession in 🇩🇪 & elsewhere and its limited knowledge of Italy, (formerly) anti-empirical & -histrcl bias not blameless here. True re-thinking only took root in last years pre-COVID, reached institutions w/ COVID & NextGenEU programmes. Too late for post-GFC moment. 26/n
OK. So what now?
Paper is diagnostic, does not develop a new reform programme. But perhaps three-pronged approach cld be explored. 1) inclusive structural reforms: courts, rule of law, tax-enforcement, anti-corruption, also stronger incentives for good firm management. 27/n
2) Investment in public administration, education, healthcare, railroads, green & digital infrastructure (NRRP good start here). 3) Industrial policy to overcome core-periphery dynamic in manufacturing (still the heart of the Italian economy!) 28/n
Beyond this, single biggest challenge remains: breaking up rent-seeking structures & transforming Italy's political capitalism from the extractive-malcoordinated to the cooperative-productive kind. Easier said than done.
Back in March I published this paper on the relationship between capitalism & democracy and didn't do my usual summary thread. It's just been switched to open access AND the German translation is out this week. So now is the time!
The paper's Q: how have key figures in the history of thought understood the relationship between democracy & capitalism?
The answer:
- it's a story in 3 acts
- prior to ~1950s, most thought dem & cap can't go together
- it's Modernization Theory that flips the script in 50s
Act 1: starting in the 18th C, plenty of Anglo- (Hume, Smith, Madison) & Francophone (Constant, Guizot) thinkers can't see universal suffrage and private property going together. If the many get the vote, they'll soak the rich. That was the widespread suspicion.
I tried to thread together the recent debates (esp from @NewStatesman@NLR and @PhenomenalWorld) around markets & planning, policy & politics of green transformation. Punchline: planning is good policy; political hope lies in tipping points. 🧵 1/n
1st, policy. As I’ve argued in @FT before, planning is essential to deliver rapid transformation. Ignore dogmatic planning-vs-markets arguments. Focus on specifics of this case. Here, mkt-coordinated investment runs into 3 problems, b/c transformation means high uncertainty. 2/n
1) Under high uncertainty, the transmission mechanism from externality pricing to investment choices becomes precarious. The links between externality-pricing-adjusted prices and expected future profits fray. Keynesian beauty contest takes over. 3/n
Crypto is like a housing bubble on crack. Why? Mini-thread.
A classic housing bubble has two ingredients: an inherently scarce asset (land) plus out-of-control credit creation (usually b/c of some "financial innovation" that gets around previous leverage limits) (1/n)
This maps 1-to-1 onto crypto. 1. The inherently scarce "assets" are the core "currencies": bitcoin, ethereum, etc. Their proof-of-work design generates human-made but real scarcity. Their use-case for criminal activity guarantees their status as asset in some minimal sense (2/n)
2. The out-of-control credit creation is provided by the so-called stablecoins, tether, USDC etc. Allegedly, they are backed by high quality liquid assets. But weirdly enough, no one of repute is allowed to check that (3/n)
THREAD: It's a distribution- not an inflation time bomb that's ticking.
Why? In Europe, inflation is sectorally concentrated, esp. in energy & food. It's bottleneck- (and savings-overhang-), not wage-driven. We're temporarily poorer than expected. (1/n)
Put simply, there is less food / gas / semiconductors / wood / etc. than anticipated. The problem here is not widespread inflation, but "who takes this hit on the chin"? It's not a massive hit, economies are holding up well, but still, that's a question of distribution. (2/n)
It may ofc TURN into an inflation problem. If rich, middle class and poor all have the political power to shield themselves against taking the hit, we would see a generalised inflation tax. 1970s scenario. But given recent wage data, this currently seems unlikely in Europe. (3/n)
My article on the political economy of deindustrialisation is out in CHS. Core claim: a Cold War comparison can teach us what features of democratic capitalism enabled this contentious process to go ahead. Gist in a 🧵: (1/n)
What’s the puzzle? In 1970s, the West struggled mightily with deindustrialisation. Inflation, strikes, terrorism, instability. Strong trade unions put up fierce resistance. The East looked coercive but stable, industrialised but w/ weaker productivity (2/n).
Hence expectation: the East might deindustrialise, to take workers out of heavy industry to boost light industry, to put more stuff in shops. Western gvts, in contrast, might be reticent to permit/foster deindustrialisation, since hard to control social/political fall-out. (3/n)
Our understanding of the Merkel years shapes our agenda & priorities going forward. I got a bit frustrated with many of the retrospectives I've seen so far, so did a take of my own. Alas in German (link: bit.ly/39xisdu), but here's a 🧵 with what I see as key bits:
1. Many criticise (& some praise) Merkel for a lack of vision, for "only" managing. When it comes to economics, I think that's fundamentally the wrong take. She identified two big challenges early on, formulated a strategic response to them & followed through for years.
2. The two challenges: demographic change and (esp. & near-obsessively) globalisation. Those themes pervade many a speech & decision of her chancellorship. Her strategy: low deficits and competitiveness. She articulated a coherent supply-side vision of growth & stuck to it.