Ben Southwood Profile picture
Oct 16, 2023 43 tweets 16 min read Read on X
Although induced demand is not a helpful concept, and roads are useful way of generating agglomeration benefits, roads (and private cars) have two big costs.
One is the externalities they cause. Another is the land they use. These have important implications.
As promised, a🧵
First my thread and post explaining how roads satisfy a latent demand for journeys, make housing cheaper by opening up much more land for productive development, support economic agglomeration, and helped start the Industrial Revolution.
The lesson we should take from this is *not*, however, that roads are always the best transport mode, that historical schemes to bulldoze our cities for them were good ideas, and that we should push against every scheme for pedestrianisation and reducing traffic in city centres. Image
The first issue is that cars take up a lot of space relative to the person they are transporting. Online urbanists have pointed this out so many times that you might think it's a canard, but it is important. Including stopping distances, cars take up the space of 20 people. Image
This means that if lots of people want to do exactly the same trip, then despite the fact cars have engines, they're often slower at moving lots of people than just walking, as you have to squeeze so much extra material through the available space. fastcompany.com/3063344/these-…
Cars have also got much bigger over time as we have got richer (on the demand side) and more efficient/productive at making them (on the supply side). This makes for a much nicer drive, but it worsens the space costs of driving. Image
For roads like motorways, which are mostly in the countryside, this doesn't really matter. Road links between cities are very important, and the alternative use of the land is usually just farming, worth about £10,000 per acre (£25,000 per hectare). Image
Land in cities, by contrast, is very scarce, especially in the centre. Land in Westminster, London's most expensive borough, averages £93 million per hectare, and that's with today's planning constraints. london.gov.uk/sites/default/…
A plot of land in Westminster without any planning constraints would go for quite a lot more. 49 Park Lane went for £3,300 per square foot. At 55 storeys (like the Hilton down the road), 1/2 hectare would have about 1 million square feet of usable space – £3.3 billion worth. Image
So land in the most prime areas can be over a million times more valuable than land outside cities. This is of course, why we build upwards when land is scarce, and we build at low density in low value areas, since we have ample cheap land. cdn.auckland.ac.nz/assets/busines…
Image
This is also part of the reason why urban railways have often been shifted underground. (The other part of the reason is the second half of the thread: the noise and pollution externalities railways have, especially steam railways.)
Just look how many more people could get down a Manhattan street in the early 1910s compared to today
All of NYC's bridges carried more people daily 100 years ago, before the lanes were given over to cars. The Brooklyn Bridge had 426,000 crossings then vs 178,000 now
London has 2m railway and 5m tube journeys each day – on the 1% of its land that is railways and stations. There are about 6m trips (incl bother passenger and driver) on the 12% of its land that is road.


gov.uk/government/sta…
tfl.gov.uk/corporate/abou…
content.tfl.gov.uk/technical-note…
Image
The more busy roads you have in a city the more pedestrians get slowed down by constant road crossing. My experience is that walking in NYC is tortuous compared to London as you have to stop at every block. worksinprogress.news/p/notes-on-pro…
This suggests we want to direct driving around the centre of cities with bypasses and ring roads. Roads in the centre should mostly be for access. Where possible, arterials should go underground as they approach the centre, just like metros and cables.
Take Rennes (France) and Bristol (UK), which have core cities and metropolitan areas of roughly the same population. Rennes is neatly ringed, Bristol has major roads driving right through the centre. My story implies the Rennes approach is superior.
Image
Image
So the first problem with roads and private car travel is that they are extremely space inefficient, meaning that they are inappropriate in the centre of cities.

The second problem is that they have large spillover costs, especially noise and air pollution.
Notice anything about this fine-grained map of Nitrogen Dioxide pollution? Things get worse as you get to the centre, but above all, pollution is driven by roads. The same is true for PM2.5s and other air pollutants. Image
I've written before about how bad air pollution likely is, even though we have almost conquered the absolute worst pollutant, lead. worksinprogress.co/issue/scientif…
Image
Road use is the biggest cause of air pollution in the UK. Everyone who lives near a big road can smell and taste it. uk-air.defra.gov.uk/assets/documen…
Switching to electric vehicles is going to help (probably halving the problem), but they will not completely eliminate local air pollution from cars.
What's more electric vehicles make very little difference to noise pollution above 20mph (though below 20mph they emit only that glorious warm drone sound). Image
People *hate* noise pollution, so much so that Studies have been seeing its effect on house prices since the 1970s – one 1976 paper found that prices went steadily up for the first 1,150 feet as the house moved away from the I-495 in North Springfield, Virginia. Image
A more recent Swedish study found that every decibel of extra road noise cut 0.6% from a property's value. Being in the loudest places cut 30% off the property's price. citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/document?repid…
Studies around the world have found similar results (I will share more in a post later). And the same thing is found for aeroplane noise. Each decibel above 45 (roughly the sound of light rain) wiped €1,900 of the value of Dutch properties in 2009. sciencedirect.com/science/articl…
People just really hate noise, and aeroplanes and cars are the two biggest sources. Each decibel is generally worth 0.5% to 3% of home value. Image
This is why people like cul-de-sacs. They don't want loud, polluting, dangerous traffic going past their front door. They want their kids to be able to play in the street. They want to have tea with their neighbours.
This is why people pay more for homes on cul-de-sacs. 29% more.
This is why developers will build all new neighbourhoods as cul-de-sacs (or something close) if they're allowed to: because buyers prefer them.

Image
Image
Image
Similarly, the Great Estates that once owned swathes of London always blocked through traffic if they could – though their biggest concerns (like driving cattle to market) are not quite the same as we have today. Image
All this harm from noise and pollution (and danger) means that we should try, where possible, to keep traffic away from residential streets. This means bypasses and ring roads.
When you have a credible bypass, then even without significant driving restrictions in the centre, you will see most of the traffic just go the quickest, most convenient route on the infrastructure meant for it. This is absolutely clear to me from driving around Spain. Image
This was the idea behind the Buchanan Report – Traffic in Towns: build good dedicated road infrastructure to drag traffic away from city centres and residential streets. It was also the idea behind London's failed Ringways project.
Image
Image
Right now there is a huge controversy over Low Traffic Neighbourhoods in the UK, which take existing residential streets in cities, and turn them into cul-de-sacs for cars (but retain access for quiet, non-polluting modes of transport).
I think that the LTN controversy could be made to go away if it was paired with improving arterial infrastructure at the same time so as well as being a win for locals, it was a win for those who were used to driving through and saw that taken from them without a say. Image
If we could build tunnels much more cheaply – say, as cheaply as Norway do – then we could make neighbourhoods quieter and cleaner without hurting those who depend on car transport.
As well as trying to shift traffic off minor residential streets, and out of city centres, what else can we do to reduce the harm of roads (which we need as vital infrastructure). One thing is just waiting. Electric cars get better every year. Hopefully they will take over soon. Image
But this will take a while, and my lungs are suffering now. This is the idea behind the ULEZ, which I think was initially a good idea – even though I had to change my car to be compliant. I'm not so sure about the recent expansion to low density outer suburbs. Image
There's more. I recently learned that other countries put noise barriers on their roads, especially on viaducts. Here are some pictures from Warsaw and Katowice. They even make roads look nicer if you grow plants on them.


Image
Image
Image
Image
Many sound barriers claim reductions of 15db or more, which is approximately the difference between nearby heavy traffic and the sound of rain. Image
These two facts: that roads are essential infrastructure, but also cause harm to those nearby, suggests there is space for a win-win political compromise. More roads in the right places, fewer cars in the wrong places. More agglomeration, less noise where it matters.
Roads are really great actually. But although we definitely want more of them, we should try and keep traffic as far away from residential streets and the places we live, laugh, and love as possible open.substack.com/pub/bensouthwo…

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Ben Southwood

Ben Southwood Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @bswud

Mar 26
Cars use a lot of land. Despite this, many cities depend entirely on the car and get by fine. This can all be explained with one 1963 paper by RJ Smeed, the British transport planner who invented 'Smeed's Law'. This paper shocked me and changed my worldview! 🧵 Image
Start by assuming *everyone* commutes to work by car. This is the land-hungriest option possible. Going by rail, because it is faster than walking, uses the least – 1 sqft. Then walking. then a bus. All the way to a car with driver only which needs up to 100 sqft. Image
Let's assume that everyone works in the city centre, which is a circle, and lives in the suburbs, which are a doughnut around that circle. Image
Read 18 tweets
Sep 23, 2024
Since 1990, France has built more motorway than the entirety we have in the UK. None of this has cost the French government a centime – private companies fronted the capital, and those driving pay for them through tolls. And their top speed limit is 11mph higher!
Image
Image
This relentless drive to build is why France is more productive than the UK per hour, and approximately as rich as the UK, despite regulation, taxes, and unions
Toll roads are not foreign to Britain. In 1600 Britain’s roads had deteriorated so far that they were worse than during the reign of King Alfred. By 1750 we had the finest roads in Europe. All due to tolling. Image
Read 4 tweets
Sep 23, 2024
Before 1940, housing in the UK got cheaper like any other good, as technology made land more productive (steel frames, reinforced concrete, electric lifts), and more interchangeable (buses, trams, cars, roads, railways). That all stopped after the Second World War. 🧵 Image
In 1938, local councils had the power to plan, and the right to refuse any development they liked, just as now. But after the Second World War, two things changed. Both dramatically reduced the incentive for councils to grant permissions. The results are famous. Image
Before 1938, councils were obliged to pay compensation if they reduced development rights below the national standard of (roughly) development. They could do this in the country, where land was inaccessible and low value, but it was expensive to refuse permission near cities.
Read 8 tweets
Sep 22, 2024
In just five years, the UK's Central Electricity Board built the National Grid, with 4,000 miles of cables, and 26,000 pylons. In 1937, a group of impatient, rebellions engineers switched the connections on without permission. The price of electricity collapsed. Image
By 1932 our government scrapped mortgage regulations and First World War-era rent controls, leading to ourmost dramatic ever housing boom. Growth was so rapid (and America's Great Depression so deep) that for one year, we were the richest country in the world again.
Image
Image
During the same time we built an enormous number of new roads, extended tubes and railways, and more.
Image
Image
Read 5 tweets
Aug 7, 2024
The main two ways that cities have expanded in history are speculative outward growth, and steady urban and suburban intensification. But there is a third way: masterplanned new towns. If done well, new towns can be a brilliant way of growing cities. 🧵 Image
Everyone is familiar with speculative developer-led outward growth, of which there are thousands of acres around all major cities, from London’s Victorian and Edwardian railway suburbs to American ‘sprawl’.

Image
Image
Image
Urban and suburban intensification are familiar too, having created the revered apartment blocks of New York’s Upper West Side, the mansion apartments of Chelsea and Marylebone, and these pictured blocks in Vienna.
Read 17 tweets
Jun 23, 2024
Coming from a country with a strong communitarian ethos based on solidarity, safety, equality, and minimising risk of harm or upset, the UK, it’s interesting to visit one with a national character more based around freedom, independence, and progress at any cost, France. 🧵
The UK has very low speed limits — the top one is only around 110kmh, and these are enforced aggressively with radars and cameras to make sure few die on roads. By contrast the top French speed limit is about 82mph, and it is rarely enforced. The priority is on speedy movement.
Image
Image
You actually reach these speeds because motorways are tolled. I spent €60 on tolls today; in exchange I put the cruise control on at 130kph for hours at a time. French attitude to paying for good things is relaxed. In egalitarian UK, the public prefers equal traffic for all.
Image
Image
Read 7 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us!

:(