Michael Pettis Profile picture
Mar 24 12 tweets 3 min read Read on X
1/12
"The new elite project is industrial policy, with a focus on creating national champions," Raghuram Rajan says, adding that "countries will have to relearn the lesson that governments are not good at picking winners."

Neither claim is true.

ft.com/content/73bf74…
2/12
US industrial policy, for example, is not about creating national champions but about protecting domestic industries from very aggressive beggar-thy-neighbor policies implemented elsewhere. The US share of global manufacturing has declined sharply over the past few...
3/12
decades, even as other advanced (and less-advanced) economies have used very successful industrial policies to increase their shares, directing massive subsidies to their manufacturing sectors even as they externalize the cost by running large, persistent trade surpluses.
4/12
In that case the point of industrial policy in the US is mainly to reduce the extent to which the US must absorb the costs of industrial and trade policies implemented elsewhere. In fact this is a very important point that Rajan misses.

carnegieendowment.org/chinafinancial…
5/12
Because of its role of great absorber of global savings imbalances, the US is not able to choose to reject industrial policy. As long as imbalances in one part of the world must be balanced in another, the US is already subject to industrial policy, like it or not.
6/12
That's because when a large economy forces its consumers to subsidize the domestic production of its manufacturers, by dumping the resulting excess savings into the US economy, this cannot help but force an opposite adjustment in the US economy.
7/12
This means US manufacturers are forced by these inflows to subsidize US consumers, so that the global economy balances. The US, in other words, is already subject to industrial policy, except that instead of one designed by Americans, it is designed by US trade partners.
8/12
It is also not true that governments cannot "pick winners". While it is easy to find cases of industrial policy that did not succeed in advancing development and economic growth, it is just as easy to find cases in which it succeeded spectacularly.
9/12
The US, Germany, Japan, South Korea, China and many other countries have benefitted enormously from clever industrial policies implemented at the right time. In fact you can reasonably make the case that the US invented successful industrial policy.
10/12
That leads to a more general criticism of Rajan's claims. To say that industrial policy – or, for that matter, that trade deficits, tariffs, closed capital accounts etc. – are "bad", strikes me as being statements more of economic faith than of economic history.
11/12
They are just too general to be true. What economists should be doing, rather than encouraging the faithful, is to examine and explain the conditions under which such policies are likely to lead to development and growth and the conditions under which they aren't.
12/12
The US economy should not simply balance industrial policies abroad. Continuing to lose global manufacturing share simply because Germany, Japan and China want to increase their shares strikes me as exactly the kind of industrial policy we should stop implementing.

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Michael Pettis

Michael Pettis Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @michaelxpettis

Mar 25
1/10
"China’s high-tech sector is driving an increasing amount of demand for goods and services in the world’s second-biggest economy, and its contribution could rival real estate by 2026, according to Bloomberg Economics."

via @technologybloomberg.com/news/articles/…
2/10
"With the property sector forecast to continue shrinking in the coming years," BE adds, "the fast growth of high tech industries and their increasing economic weight make them a promising growth engine."

BE may be making the same mistake analysts made in 2022-23.
3/10
When we first saw China switch investment out of the property sector and into manufacturing, after the 2021 clampdown on the property sector, many analysts argued that this was the solution to China's over-reliance on non-productive investment to drive the economy.
Read 10 tweets
Mar 22
1/7
More and more prominent Chinese economists are calling for fiscal transfers to the household sector. In this recent piece, Zhang Jun, Fudan's dean of economics, argues that Beijing should embark on "a comprehensive strategy to support and enhance...

eastisread.com/p/zhang-jun-ad…
2/7
real household incomes, with fiscal spending directed towards families aiming to boost the real income of middle and low-income families. This approach should include a significant increase in transfer payments to families."
3/7
In my March 8 research piece for Global Source I argued that for a variety or reasons listed in the piece it was unlikely that investment in property, infrastructure or manufacturing would be enough to generate the 5% GDP growth target.
Read 7 tweets
Mar 21
1/12
The chief European economist at T Rowe Price writes about the economic consequences of financial repression: "These policies crowd out private sector investment. In the short term, this will lead to lower growth and inflation, as monies which...

ft.com/content/4ebe53…
2/12
would have been invested in the private sector capital stock are spent on public debt service and repayment instead. But in the medium term, lower accumulation of capital will result in a structurally more rigid supply side of the economy."
3/12
"When there is rise in demand," he concludes, "this will lead to higher inflation and therefore structurally higher interest rates."

It's more complicated than that. Financial repression is basically a way of transferring income from certain savers to net borrowers.
Read 12 tweets
Mar 20
1/5
FT: "The balance of trade in goods hit €28bn in January, its highest level since authorities started tracking data in 2002. Last year, the eurozone recorded a trade surplus of €64bn, in contrast with the record €335bn deficit it suffered in 2022."

ft.com/content/1e6b6f…
2/5
With the eurozone and China exporting record amounts of deficient demand into the global economy, this puts more pressure than ever on the US, the UK, Canada and developing world to protect the supply side of their domestic economies.
3/5
The irony is that EU officials have been vociferously opposed to Chinese plans to engineer an increase in its share of global manufacturing as a way as a way to resolve domestic demand weakness, but their own inability to address weak domestic demand is almost as big...
Read 5 tweets
Mar 19
1/4
Peter, I should have distinguished more clearly between subsidies for one productive sector that come at the expense of another, and subsidies for production generally that come at the expense of household demand.
2/4
While arguments can be made against the former, they can also be justified as an inevitable part of the development process because they are designed mainly to shift the basis of comparative advantage. They include Hamilton's "infant manufactures" policies.
3/4
It is the latter that is the real problem, because these subsidies work by suppressing domestic demand and externalizing the cost through trade surpluses which, in turn, forces trade partners to respond either with higher unemployment or more debt.
Read 4 tweets
Mar 19
1/14
A director at the American Enterprise Institute is warning that protectionism has run amok in the US.

Nonsense. Protectionist economies are those in which manufacturing is subsidized through direct and indirect transfers from the household sector.

ft.com/content/cdd09f…
2/14
These transfers suppress domestic demand, with the cost externalized in the form of persistent trade surpluses. The result is that protectionist economies have high manufacturing shares of GDP, weak domestic demand and persistent trade surpluses.

carnegieendowment.org/chinafinancial…
3/14
This clearly isn't the case in the US. It has a very low manufacturing share of GDP (11%, versus over 17% for the rest of the world), strong domestic demand (accounting for 24% of global GDP but nearly 27% of global consumption), and almost half of all global trade deficits.
Read 14 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us!

:(