1/12
A Tsinghua-related think tanks argues that "China should issue 30 trillion yuan in treasury bonds to swap local governments’ hidden liabilities to re-energise growth momentum and cut off financial risks at their root."
via @scmpnewssc.mp/gz8bj?utm_sour…
2/12
This would help in two ways, according to the report. It would transfer debt from local government balance sheets to the central government balance sheet, giving them more breathing space to prop up the economy, and it would reduce interest payments.
3/12
But this is what comes of treating a systemic issue incrementally. The problem is not that local governments have too much debt. The excessive debt burden of local governments is actually a symptom of the real problem. ft.com/content/630f82…
4/12
The real problem is that for over a decade local governments have had to generate enough economic activity to meet an unrealistic GDP growth target, and the only way they could do so was to engage in massive amounts of non-productive investment.
5/12
If this investment had been productive, rapid increases in debt would have been more than matched by rapid increases in GDP, as they were before 2007-09. That this "investment" since then has led to among the fastest growing debt burdens in history is proof that it wasn't.
6/12
The only meaningful way to resolve the local-government debt problem is to reduce the GDP growth target and to recognize and allocate the existing losses within the economy as efficiently as possible. This means, of course, that some sector or other will take large losses.
7/12
This will be painful, of course, but the historical precedents are pretty clear: postponing a resolution of bad debt and overvalued assets always makes it more costly, and the heavier the resulting debt burden, the harder it is to control the way in which it is resolved.
8/12
Transferring local-government debt to Beijing simply means postponing a resolution even further while ruining the only clean balance sheet left in China. Without a clean central-government balance sheet, the Chinese economy will be much more susceptible to disruption.
9/12
What about the argument that at least such a transfer will reduce debt-servicing costs? That too is questionable, and confuses the systemic problem of Chinese debt with the incremental problem of local government debt.
10/12
That's because while lowering interest rates benefits the specific borrower, it does not make the debt disappear. It just transfers the debt servicing costs, in this case from local governments to the banking system, and the banks already urgently need to be recapitalized.
11/12
Every RMB saved in debt-servicing cost, in other words, increases the government's contingent obligations by the same amount, requiring an additional RMB in recapitalization. This is like taking money from one pocket and putting it in another, and declaring yourself richer.
12/12
This is not just a Chinese problem, of course. Most governments will postpone resolving their debt problems as long as they can, but, as Japan showed in the period from the 1980s through the 2000s, you cannot postpone the cost of non-productive investment forever.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
1/8 A China Finance 40 Forum research piece by Yu Fei and Guo Kai argues that when adjusted for purchasing power and for volumes, Chinese consumption is much higher than the current consensus. pekingnology.com/p/chinas-consu…
2/8 They are probably right, although I would caution that using purchasing power adjustments in a system in which producer prices are highly subsidized by households is likely to substantially overstate the real extent of the purchasing power adjustment.
3/8 But while Yu and Guo do not misconstrue the implications of their work for China's internal and external imbalances, I suspect that quite a few analysts will argue that this study shows that China does not have an underconsumption problem.
1/6 A decision by China to offer more debt relief could be a “game changer for the poor and the system,” said Kevin Gallagher, the director of the Boston University Global Development Policy Center. “It’s really in China’s strategic interest to do that.”
2/6 Ironically, debt relief is also in the economic interest of creditor countries, especially if, as in the case of China, the economy is highly dependent on export surpluses.
That's because capital flows are just the reverse of trade flows.
3/6 To put it another way, every dollar an overly-indebted developing country earns from its exports must be recycled, either in the form of debt repayment or in the form of imports. The less that goes to the former, the more that is available for the latter.
1/8 The euro is up 14% against the dollar this year, as well as against the yuan (11%) and the yen (4%), driven by financial inflows rather than by economic fundamentals (i.e. higher relative productivity grown).
2/8 If sustained, it will almost certainly have an adverse impact on EU manufacturing. In that case ECB rate cuts may keep unemployment from rising (by boosting domestic consumption), but they won't prevent the EU economy from shifting out of manufacturing towards services.
3/8 It seems absurd that major, open economies like the EU and the US should allow imbalances in their domestic economies to be determined by changes in global financial flows, and especially by changes in the way less open surplus countries decide to balance their surpluses.
1/4 I just finished Martin Daunton's excellent survey and analysis of the last 100 years of globalization. There is an enormous amount of material here (nearly 900 pages) and it may not be an easy read for those who aren't already very familiar with much of this history.
2/4 But for those who are, or who want to be, it's well worth the effort. While the book is ostensibly about the process of globalization, and the role of government and government institutions in that process, especially in pivotal periods during the 1930-40s, the 1970s and...
3/4 in the past decade, a major theme is the enormous distortions caused by the unfettered flow of capital, the ways in which these flows dislocated domestic economies, and the various (mostly unsuccessful) attempts individually and collectively to control them.
1/4 Good John Authers article on business profits in the US: "After-tax profits account for an unprecedented 10.7% of gross domestic product, when in the last 50 years of the 20th century, they never exceeded 8%."
@johnauthers_ bloomberg.com/opinion/articl…
2/4 "The only time approaching their current share of the economy was in 1929 on the eve of the Great Crash. If the nation is to deal with inequality, money must be redistributed from somewhere; corporate profits are an obvious source of funds."
3/4 Speaking of 1929, we need to re-read Marriner Eccles (FDR's Fed chairman) on the relationship between income inequality, weak domestic demand, rising debt needed to boost domestic demand, and the eventual collapse in production once rising debt can no longer be sustained.
1/4 Caixin: "China is in dire need of more domestic consumption as global uncertainties hamper external demand. Key to this is increasing incomes, a Chinese economics professor said at the Summer Davos Forum in Tianjin on Thursday."
2/4 It's good that there is finally a consensus that low consumption is China's most serious economic problem, and the main cause of its other problems (soaring debt, deflation, overinvestment in infrastructure and manufacturing, over-reliance on a rising trade surplus).
3/4 It's also good that there's a growing consensus that the only sustainable way to raise consumption is to raise household incomes.
But it isn't yet fully acknowledged that China doesn't need rising consumption per se so much as rising consumption relative to GDP.