The case ended up hinging on a question that seems pretty unrelated to trade:
Does the totality of a country’s legal system say anything about its moral values? Thread wto.org/english/news_e…
It was not unexpected that the WTO would find the levies in violation of the most-favored nation rules.
These are at the core of the global trading system, and ensure that the US generally gives every WTO member the same treatment.
The US did not even contest the point.
Rather, the US defense was that the MFN-violating trade actions were taken to further the cause of public morals – citing Article XX(a) of the GATT. wto.org/english/docs_e…
This was a creative defense, and probably the best one that the US could have made.
The argument is simple: the concentration and dependence of the US on a regime built in opposition to liberal values causes not only economic damage, but also erodes a sense of right and wrong.
As evidence for what is considered “right”, the US referenced the entirety of the US federal and state legal code. On “wrong,” the evidence was the pervasive use in China of theft and market-countering industrial policy.
These laws and practices embody fairness and help preserve democracy, according to the US.
Thus, the tariffs on China were important not only because of what they signal to trading partners, but what they signal to US citizens about what will and will not be tolerated.
Leave to the side whether industrial policy in China or the US is actually wrong (it’s not – see below), Trump’s strategy is smart (it’s largely not), or whether US law and politics doesn’t display hypocrisy at times (it does). rooseveltinstitute.org/publications/i…
It’s gutsy, and pretty mission creepy, for a trio of trade lawyers to tackle big philosophical questions like whether the entirety of a society and its laws say something about its values. But @scottjshapiro@Camila_Vergara@BLMcKean et al needn't worry about competition just yet
To China, any policy to protect public morals would need to be product-specific, like keeping out only specific imports deemed objectionable because of some inherent quality embodied in the item (e.g. gambling services, seal meat, etc.)
The panel tended to agree: any policy aimed at protecting morals would need to be pretty targeted. Moreover, every pronouncement or request for comment would need to specifically mention the objective of protecting public morals.
Granted, a lot of good government has been eroded away in the Trump era. But I don’t think it would be a net positive for society if policymakers had to explicitly say every time they were acting in what they saw as moral.
Indeed, the bigness of the policy action – high tariffs on hundreds of billions of trade – should be an indication that the administration sees the China relationship as pretty problematic from a values standpoint.
The panel didn’t see it that way. Indeed, the fact that the US conducted a type of cost-benefit analysis before announcing the tariffs (and that it permitted affected importers to apply for exclusions) ended up being "proof" that the policy was “economic” as opposed to “moral.”
This discussion is a bit of a tell: contemporary trade agreements increasingly contain provisions that further cost-benefit analysis and US-style regulatory review.
But if countries start using these techniques, they leave themselves open to critique that they’re acting “economically” rather than in support of other goals.
Indeed, the panel indicated that even considerations of public morals defenses had to be put in the context of the GATT’s preamble – which enshrines ongoing trade liberalization as the purpose of the agreement panelists are called upon to interpret.
The WTO report leaves it pretty evident that the body as currently constituted can’t be used by the US to counter China’s economic model. Even US allies took China’s side. @AmPhoenixTrade
One upshot of the decision: it might force trade policymakers to speak more about the morality behind their policies. If they might ever want to avail themselves of the public morals defense, it could be prudent to do so.
How Industrial Policy Gets Done: Frontline Lessons from Three Federal Officials
I interviewed @katenrg @RonnieChatterji & Satyam Khanna about their time helping set up the offices that are building middle-out economics.
🧵 rooseveltinstitute.org/publications/h…
For arguably the first time since the Roosevelt administration, there's an acknowledged and massive effort to influence the composition and practices of industries operating in the US.
Trillions in public and private capital are moving into communities all over the 🇺🇸.
These industrial policy efforts are not falling from the sky: they're being driven by real people, trying to solve problems in real time.
In this brief, we were interested in one group of said people: the advisors in federal agencies like @ENERGY @EPA & @CommerceGov.
In an election year where both political parties have deployed tariffs as a tool of statecraft, @DemJournal asked @ENPancotti @mattyglesias and me to debate the pros and cons, when tariffs work, and when they are damaging.
🧵 democracyjournal.org/magazine/74/ar…
Liz and I were assigned the "pro-tariff" side of the debate, though we offer caveats.
Our main argument is that it's too easy to put tariffs in a politics/public choice box, when in fact there are long established market failure reasons for their use.
Moreover, having taking the fork in the road towards industrial policy subsidies to internalize positive externalities from decarbonization, it would have been unwise policy/an abdication of fiduciary responsibility to allow imports to wipe out new clean industries.
This is the result of a 4 year review since the beginning of the Biden administration, which has been evaluating whether various Chinese policies comport with US trade laws.
Fantastic panel @HarvardMWC on lessons we can learn from global experiences with industrial policy, with @rodrikdani @straightedge @myrto_kaloup and @rohlamba.
Myrto talking Chinese shipbuilding excess capacity. Has 50-70% market share today.
@Rohan_Sandhu Myrto says Chinese shipbuilding not efficient when taken on their own, but had clear benefits in terms of outward exports / lowering transportation costs / enhancing military capacity. nber.org/papers/w26075
NEW from me @RooseveltFwd: How Biden's comments on US Steel's tie up with Japan's Nippon company indicate what a Foreign Policy for the Middle Class might look like in practice. rooseveltforward.org/2024/04/03/bid…
The idea of reorienting foreign economic policy to build labor power and combat inequality was articulated by @JakeSullivan46 @jennifermharris and others in a series of essays and reports in 2019-20. foreignpolicy.com/2020/02/07/ame…
This doesn't mean that traditional diplomacy has to die out. Indeed, as @dimi and @KanaInagaki report, even after Biden's comments, the US and Japan are slated to make the biggest upgrade to their alliance in 60 years. ft.com/content/df9999…
BREAKING from @AP: @Energy agency announces $6 billion to slash emissions in industrial facilities.
@JenMcDermottAP @anniesartor @SecGranholm @alizaidi46 and me on why this is game changing, and could allow the US to catch up/ lead on industrial decarb. apnews.com/article/climat…
The mix of projects funded here is exciting, including a range of technologies to be deployed by US leader @CLE_CLF, and even projects by Sweden's SSAB. energy.gov/oced/industria…