The next few years are going to test how much deflationary capacity there is in the US and global economy from technology, debt, and demographics to absorb the inflationary increase in broad money.
A thread.
In terms of overall fiscal and monetary policy, including the wartime-like fiscal response that we’ve seen over the past year, the 2020s so far have structural similarities to the 1940s.
Here’s the long-term debt cycle, for example:
During the 1930s, monetary policy hit the limit of what it can do against the prospect of a private debt bubble, and so it was then a massive fiscal response in the 1940s, forced by external factors (the war), that pumped inflation:
Similarly, the 2010s had a partial unwinding of a private debt bubble and a large monetary response, but limited fiscal response.
It wasn’t until the pandemic in 2020 that policymakers brought out the fiscal cannon.
Deflation proponents often point out that the money multiplier (broad money as a multiple of the monetary base) is low right now. That’s true.
However, the only other time it was this low (the 1940s), was actually quite inflationary.
Some people dismiss the 1940s inflationary period as being just transient spikes of inflation due to specific temporary shortages.
And indeed, the inflation of that era came in bursts:
However, the consumer price index never returned to baseline after those inflationary spikes. Those spikes each brought broad prices up to permanently higher levels.
From 1940-1952, the consumer price index went up 90% and stayed there forever.
The reason those 1940s price increases were not transient, is because behind the surface of commodity shortages there was a massive increase in the broad money supply due to fiscal spending, which was effectively monetized.
In other words, if extreme fiscal policy were not occurring in the 1940s, prices would go back to normal after their brief spike from temporary shortages.
The reason they didn’t go back to normal was because the currency itself was devalued.
And that’s not a criticism of policymakers in the era. For investors, there were winners and losers in that scenario depending on what asset classes they were primarily in.
Since it was a currency devaluation, it was cash and bondholders that took the brunt of it.
The deflationary capacity of the current economy is huge, due to automation, software, high debt, wealth concentration, and aging demographics.
And policymakers will be putting that deflationary force to the test.
If they can do a large fiscal burst (spending without associated tax increases), and there is no big inflationary response, then the incentive exists for them to do it again. And again. And again. The only limiter would be obvious inflation.
To the extent that broad money supply goes up a lot and CPI and bond yields stay relatively low, then the money tends to pile into financial assets, since it has to go somewhere. Lately that’s what the situation has been.
In April/May (reported May/June), we’ll get some higher year-over-year CPI prints from low base effects.
After that, broad inflation levels will partly depend on what happens with the next round of fiscal stimulus: if it passes, how big it is, what it targets, etc.
Some of my chart legends didn't update properly. Money multiplier should be rhs here (aka right axis), not lhs. The others are lhs.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
Here's a thread about social media decentralization.
A couple years ago, I tried to "like" one of Doomberg's posts about a platform, and I literally saw the heart fill up, and then drain out of it like blood. I'd never seen that before.
Twitter said me liking that was disabled:
Then, when I tried to search on Twitter for that certain platform that apparently can't be named, the search results would replace it with "newsletter" in my search of the network, which was kind of Orwellian:
Even now, I don't say the obvious visible name of that platform that starts with an S. Since an unconscious algo might derank it.
Maybe that's not an issue anymore. Probably.
The funny thing is that I didn't even post about that platform until I couldn't. Then I did a lot.
I keep seeing the chart float around of 23 million government employees, as though that's directly cuttable by the new Department of Government Efficiency.
Keep in mind that 3 million of those are listed as federal and the other 20+ million are state/local.
A thread. 🧵
Now, quantifying the actual federal workforce is actually nontrivial.
-Are we talking civilian, or military too (1.3M)?
-Are we including postal workers (550k)?
Along with Steve Lee @moneyball and Ren @0xren_cf, I co-authored a paper that analyzes the process and risks of how Bitcoin upgrades its consensus rules over time, from a technical & economic perspective.
Bitcoin is hard to change by design, and the methods of how it changes have evolved as the network has grown.
In the paper, we analyze what consensus is, and how different types of entities have different incentives and powers during the course of a potential consensus change.