Hanno Lustig Profile picture
Sep 13 23 tweets 7 min read
📣The secular decline in rates may not have boosted U.S. fiscal capacity as much as you think, but it definitely has exposed the U.S. Treasury to more interest rate risk. 🧵

based on #BPEA piece brookings.edu/bpea-articles/…
@SVNieuwerburgh @ProfJiang @MindyXiaolan
1/in standard models, government debt is fully backed by the collateral, future primary surpluses (S). So, a natural way to assess fiscal capacity is to measure the dollar value today of this stream of future surpluses
2/ Let’s assume for a second that the federal government runs surpluses, spending and tax revenue that are a constant fraction of GDP. The dollar value in 2021 of future S is given by the multiple on a claim to GDP, the steady-state S/Y and 2021 GDP.
3/ only GDP is risky here and so the claim to GDP is priced using a discount rate that includes a GDP risk premium (unlevered equity premium), roughly the risk premium on stocks issued by firms that have not issued debt.
4/At the end of 2021, this multiple was around 85, according to our estimates, because of low long yields, and low risk premia. As a result, you’d need a steady-state S of 1.16% to rationalize the current debt/output ratio (at the end of 2021) : 1.16%*85=0.99
5/The decline in long rates over the past two decades has boosted this multiple to 85. This multiple means that you can issue 85% extra debt/output per 1% of primary surplus (as fraction of GDP). A high multiple!
6/But that decline in rates only increases fiscal capacity if you’re actually expected to run primary surpluses, and the CBO does not project any surpluses in the next 30 years. CBO projects deficits of 3.19% until 2052.
7/This simple calculation assumes that S's are constant over the business cycle as a fraction of GDP. But S's typically decline as the economy enters a recession. So, this calculation is really too optimistic. The actual PDV of S is smaller, because S is riskier.
8/ We feed in the actual CBO projections for the primary S in the next 30 yrs and for future debt/output in 2052, and simply back out the PDV of all future projected S, assuming that the debt in 2052 is fully backed by primary S accruing after 2052. (generous assumption)
9/ We (generously) assume the Treasury runs steady-state S/Y of 2.16% starting in 2052 (so that the projected debt/output ratio of 185% projected by the CBO for 2052 is fully backed by surpluses)
10/ if you translate projected deficits until 2052 and the S after 2052 back into 2021 dollars, you end up with $12.4 trillion << $22.40 trillion
11/ Treasury earns seigniorage revenue from the convenience yields on U.S . Treasurys. We assume that this revenue is a constant fraction of GDP going forward. That provides another $4 trillion.
12/The secular decline in rates over the past decades has not really boosted fiscal capacity of the US that much, because the US is not projected to run surpluses any time soon, but it has increased the duration of the surpluses, which occur after 2052.
13/ This means that the Treasury is highly exposed to interest rate risk. A 100 bps increase in rates (all else equal) triggers an increase in steady-state S/Y of 2.67% after 2052 (so that higher D/Y in 2052 is fully backed by surpluses).
14/ What accounts for the discrepancy between the market's valuation of U.S. Treasurys and our measure: 3 scenarios: 1/ market anticipates major fiscal correction relative to CBO projections (we're wrong). 2/ market anticipates Japan-style financial repression 3/ market is wrong
15/ what about the argument that the debt can always be rolled over at the risk-free rate? well, in our approach, the debt is risky (i.e., it does not have a zero beta because the tax claim is riskier than the spending claim) and cannot be rolled over at the risk-free rate.
16/ moreover, in a model with risky g, g<<risk-free in every state of the world would generate arbitrage opportunities for private investors borrowing at the risk-free and earning g by loing in equity.
17/ here is the decade-by-decade overview of the effective cost of U.S. federal debt (r) (the return on all marketable Treasury debt) and the nominal growth rate (g). r>g in the 80s and 90s.
18/ full slide deck here brookings.edu/wp-content/upl…
paper draft here brookings.edu/wp-content/upl…
19/of course, there are macro models in which debt is not fully backed by future S, but partly by future debt itself. in these models, typically without long-lived investors and without aggregate risk, the no-bubble constraint is violated. our approach rules out these bubbles.
20/Caution: These models do not identify the US as an obvious candidate for engineering bubbles in the debt market.
21/ helpful discussions by @WilliamGale2 and Debbie Lucas here brookings.edu/events/bpea-fa…
22/ comparison of this approach to fiscal sustainability to other approaches here macfinancesociety.files.wordpress.com/2022/08/mfs_ha…

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Hanno Lustig

Hanno Lustig Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @HannoLustig

Jul 20
1/Macro-economics is still quite US-centric, and so, many of us implicitly use the US as **the benchmark**. But the US is quite different from most countries. Especially when it comes to fiscal capacity.
2/ Just to name one big difference, the US is the world's safe asset supplier and the dollar is world's reserve currency. This allows the US to implement policies that other countries probably can't implement. that's exorbitant privilege.
3/ for example, many in the Eurozone seem convinced they've gone through a decade 1/2 of `extreme' austerity
Read 10 tweets
Jun 5
Does it matter if Europe keeps pumping Euros into 🇷🇺? Economists who claim it does not believe Putin has given Europe a huge free lunch. An explainer. 👇
1/ #1 claim📣 `We can keep injecting dollars and euros into 🇷🇺 without any real impact because Russians have absolutely no use for dollars/euros now or ever.' Underlying assumption: Permanent autarchy. The 🇷🇺 economy will be even more isolated than 🇰🇵 for the next century.
2/Hence, 🇷🇺 won’t be able to use those dollars/euros to imports goods and services, ever. So, we can just keep buying their oil and gas. Putin has given Europe a huge free lunch, collecting Europe's IOUs which are worthless to him, because Russia will be in autarchy forever
Read 9 tweets
Jun 4
1/additional export sanctions against 🇷🇺 have no effect, if (i) Russian imports are zero now, and (ii) zero in the future, and (iii) Russians have no other motive for holding dollars/euros (for example, no demand for dollar safety). dollars have to be completely useless in 🇷🇺.
2/each one of these assumptions is unrealistic. (i) is clearly not true: Russian are importing stuff. (ii) Russians will definitely import stuff in the future, (iii) Lots of demand for the safety of dollars in all countries, including 🇷🇺
3/ even when imports are close to zero now, Russians want to hold dollars/euros to buy stuff from abroad in the future or as a store of value (safe asset). the dollar/euro export revenue then allows the government to satisfy its budget constraint without printing money.
Read 4 tweets
Jun 3
🧵 with some thoughts on @M_C_Klein 's post about the economics of energy sanctions against 🇷🇺.
1/Matt's analysis focuses on the 🇷🇺 country budget constraint, but, ignores the 🇷🇺government budget constraint.
2/So, Matt's thinking is that, if Russian imports are zero now and in the future, then it does not matter whether the Russian government earns oil revenue, because they cannot import any goods or services with that oil revenue. Now or in the future.
Read 13 tweets
Jun 3
Oh my...inflation has gone global. Actually, it's been global for 2 decades. 🧵
1/yoy inflation excluding the pandemic. can you pick out the US, the UK and the Eurozone? it's hard.
2/inflation has co-moved closely across countries in the past 2 decades. so, it's not surprising that the spike in inflation is spreading across the globe. it would be more surprising if that did not happen. (OECD data) data.oecd.org/price/inflatio…
Read 7 tweets
Jun 1
1/Yesterday, the 10-year TIPS breakeven was trading at 2.69% way down from its peak at 3%. this might be partly because TIPS have become cheap relative to Treasurys.
2/If you look at inflation swaps, you see a different picture. The 10-YR zero coupon inflation swap rate is at 3%. It has come down a bit, but much less than the TIPS break-even (note: you can't directly compare the TIPS breakeven to the zero coupon inflation swap rate).
3/we can compare the inflation swap to the zero coupon breakeven. here is the gap between the 10 year zero coupon inflation swap rate and the zero coupon 10 year break-even computed by Gurkaynak et al. (these can be compared directly) gap is 35 bps. large gap. swap rate>>BE.
Read 9 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us on Twitter!

:(