Glenn Profile picture
Nov 14 17 tweets 4 min read Read on X
IMO conflating mfg goods with holistic global trade here.

China runs a mfg. goods surplus of ~$1,763B.

But it runs a structural deficit in *every other key trade category.

(moreover, the mfg. goods figure itself is likely overstated relative to underlying fund flows)
This is what’s excluded from the above number:

1️⃣ $909B of primary goods imports (food, natural resources)
2️⃣ $241B services (mainly travel/tourism)
3️⃣ $386B profits of foreign firms operating in China

As well as a 4️⃣ $258B “factoryless manufacturing” adjustment. Image
1️⃣ China has a large structural deficit in natural resources (iron ore, petroleum) and food (soybeans, corn).

e.g. China imported $332B of petroleum and $272B of ore during the period.

This brings the net goods surplus to $854B for the 12 months ending 6/30/2024, per GACC.
This figure is further adjusted by $258B to match with underlying fund flows due to the “factoryless manufacturing adjustment. I’ll get back to this later.

The brings the goods surplus on the Balance of Payments to $596B.
2️⃣ China runs a structural deficit in services, mainly driven by its “imports” of outbound travel, tourism and education.

Indeed, the principal reason why the CA surplus spiked in 2021-22 was from pandemic restrictions on travel.

It ran a $241B deficit LTM 6/30/2024, per SAFE.

This brings the overall trade surplus to $355B.
3️⃣ China runs a structural deficit where foreign companies make much larger profits in China ($386B) than Chinese firms make outside China (est. $52B).

These net profits are repatriated out of China to support jobs, income and demand in RoW.
Examples of U.S. MNCs tapping into Chinese household demand:

▪️ Apple selling ~45M iPhones p.a.
▪️ Tesla selling ~650k electric vehicles
▪️ Nike selling $5.5B worth of shoes and apparel

The huge profits these companies generate don’t show up in the goods surplus.
Chinese MNCs make significantly less on their overseas operations, as they have only recently started expanding overseas.

I’ve estimated this figure by modeling passive investment income on China’s large foreign reserve and foreign lending portfolio and taking the residual.
In the context of this debate about just how much China depends on the world (and vice versa), this figure is highly relevant, as it represents net economic value that flows out of China to RoW.

These “active” profits are also a core component of modern global trade.
This lowers the holistic trade and “active” investment balance to merely $22B, or 0.1% of China’s GDP.

Adding on the aforementioned passive investment income and some miscellaneous BoP items gets us back to the official current account surplus of $211B, or 1.2% of GDP.
4️⃣ The “factoryless manufacturing” adjustment is
part of an ongoing debate on the scale of distortion effects of “factoryless manufacturing” on trade figures reported to customs.

It represents the difference between physical flow trade measured by China Customs and the underlying funds flows used in recent BoP data tabulated by SAFE.
I’ve laid out the case on why I think the adjustments SAFE made correct these distortions and improve the accuracy of the Balance of Payments data.

Brad disagrees and instead claims China is now understating its true current account surplus by upwards of $500-600B.
Not going to get into that particular debate here.

Because even without the “factoryless manufacturing” adjustment, the trade and investment surplus (factoring in net FDI) would be $280B, which at 1.5% of GDP is 6-7x smaller than the manufactured goods surplus.
Arguing that the world doesn’t export to China by zero’ing in on a single category (manufactured goods) where it runs a surplus and ignoring every other category where it runs a structural deficit presents an unrealistic view of holistic trade in today’s complex global economy.
It’s implicitly based on a strict definition of trade (customs definitions of exports and imports, of only one category of physical exports) that doesn’t consider the complex realities of modern trade, like the hundreds of billions in profits by foreign MNCs earned in China or outbound travel and tourism by Chinese households.
It’s important that we form an objective, accurate view of China’s holistic trade relationship with the world.

It is counter-productive to rely on cherry-picked data to support exaggerated narratives like the one about how much China truly relies on global demand and its capacity to absorb exogenous shocks.
Distorted or inaccurate narratives carry the risk of suboptimal policy formulation — e.g. entering negotiations with China with an exaggerated sense of how much leverage we really have.

Or underestimating China’s own ability to retaliate.

END.

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Glenn

Glenn Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @GlennLuk

Nov 13
This resonated with me.

The concentration of gains from technology advances suggests that it needs to be packaged with well-thought-out distributional policy …
… lest the disruptive effects of tech gains lead even more disruptive and less optimal societal-level outcomes that can paradoxically torpedo ability to capture future tech progress.
This can also be generalized beyond tech to other complex trends like global outsourcing that come with similar negative externalities (disruptive effects on communities).
Read 9 tweets
Nov 12
There’s a shocking level of naivete embedded here (Rubio interview) when you walk through the practical & operational implications of trying to move this type of manufacturing.

Who is going to be responsible for setting up the factories in these locales? Image
First, remember these aren’t Gigafactories — the U.S. wants more of those, not less.

These are labor-intensive export processing factories: The ones that were offshored from this country over the last half-century, pre-dating China’s rise as a manufacturer.
Second, we are not talking about large-scale electronics factories like those run by Foxconn.

These countries are small and don’t have the scaled workforce that you need to make the unit economics work.

We are talking product categories like clothing and toys.
Read 19 tweets
Nov 10
Billy moneyballs Chinese structural reform

Guys, you’re still trying to fight demographics and replace 350 million retiring workers.

I told you, we can’t do it, and we can’t do it.

Now, what we might be able to do is recreate them.

Re-create it in the aggregate.Image
How much GDP did these workers generate last year? Image
Fifty-eight point eight trillion renminbi. Image
Read 23 tweets
Nov 10
China’s non-college-educated working-age population (maroon line below), a proxy for “blue-collar” work (farming, manufacturing, construction, services) shrinking at ~19M per year through 2040 …

… while the “attended college” population increases at ~10.6M per year.
So China needs to shed blue-collar work like labor-intensive export-processing jobs while creating new “white-collar” jobs that are a better fit for college graduates.
This drives so much of the timing and pace of structural reform, particularly in policy intervention related to industry and sectoral transition.
Read 59 tweets
Nov 9
In light of increased likelihood of increased bilateral tariffs on U.S.-China trade, it is useful to examine ST & LT impacts of key “exports” like the iPhone.

Here we consider the two aspects of the iPhone trade:
▪️ China’s role as a manufacturer
▪️ China’s role as a consumer
I put “exports” in quotes for the iPhone because although customs data officially records it as an export, China is actually a very large net importer of iPhones by dollar amount.
Customs data recorded ~$84B of global iPhone exports from China in 2022, or $457 per iPhone.

This compares to average BOM per iPhone of $270-310.

$49B of the $84B are ~124M iPhones headed to the U.S. and potentially subject to increased tariffs.
Read 34 tweets
Nov 7
Some of these instincts were right, but IMO doesn’t apportion enough blame to uncoordinated domestic strategy / poor execution.

e.g.

Trade gains should’ve been diverted to supporting impacted communities.

The offshoring of mfg supply chains shouldn’t have been so complete.
The *complete offshoring of mfg jobs broke the chain of knowledge transfer to the next generation of workers.

The reshaping of the workforce to high-value services through incentives created human capital imbalances in LT comparative advantage.
How did this happen?

One major culprit: the system is not structured to think enough about externalities.

Businesses are represented by BoDs that have a legal responsibility to one stakeholder class (owners/equity).
Read 11 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us!

:(