Relearning Economics Profile picture
Aug 11 8 tweets 2 min read Read on X
Mainstream macro blames crises on public debt or bad policy.

History tells a different story, The biggest crashes follow private debt booms , when households & firms load up on credit faster than incomes grow.
🧵1/8 Image
1929, Japan’s 1990s bust, the 2008 GFC, all preceded by surging private debt-to-GDP.

In each case, public debt rose after the crisis, as governments absorbed the fallout.

Cause and effect are backwards in the textbook story.
🧵2/8
Private debt booms are dangerous because they fuel asset bubbles and fragile balance sheets.

When cashflows falter or rates rise, defaults spike and leverage turns into a chain reaction.
🧵3/8
Unlike public debt, private debt must be serviced from incomes that can’t be printed.

When repayment strains hit, spending collapses, dragging the economy down.
🧵4/8
Minsky called it the “financial instability hypothesis”:
Stability breeds complacency, risk-taking rises, debt loads grow, until the system tips.
🧵5/8
Policy failure #1: ignoring private credit growth in macro models.

DSGE model frameworks treat debt as neutral or irrelevant.

The cycle is driven by leverage, but the models are blind to it.
🧵6/8
Policy failure #2: obsessing over public debt while letting private debt run wild.

It’s the household mortgage bubble, not the deficit, that crashes economies.
🧵7/8
If you want to prevent crises, track private debt-to-GDP, not just inflation.

The warning signs are always there if you’re willing to look.

Check out all my blogs out on this topic an more on my Patreon:
🧵8/8
patreon.com/c/relearningec…

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Relearning Economics

Relearning Economics Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @RelearningEcon

Aug 7
Fractional reserve banking" still shows up in textbooks, news, and even heterodox debates.

But the concept is dead.

Modern banking doesn’t work that way, and clinging to the term misleads more than it explains.
🧵1/9 Image
Traditionally, it meant banks held a fixed % of deposits in reserve (say 10%) and lent out the rest.

But today?

There are no reserve requirements in countries like the U.S.

Banks aren’t lending most of your money. They aren’t required to hold any.
🧵2/9
Bank lending today is constrained by:
– Capital ratios
– Liquidity rules
– Risk appetite

Banks lend when it’s profitable, not when they have “extra reserves.”

In fact, they don’t lend reserves to the public at all — only to other banks.
🧵3/9
Read 9 tweets
Jul 30
Neoclassical models treat fiscal policy as neutral in the long run, only useful in “crises.”

But this idea rests on flawed assumptions: full employment, crowding out, Ricardian equivalence, and perfect markets.

Let’s unpack why none of these hold.
🧵1/7 Image
Assumption: the economy naturally returns to full employment.

Reality: underemployment, labor market hysteresis, and demand shortfalls are persistent.

When you assume away slack, you assume away the need for fiscal intervention.
🧵2/7
Assumption: government spending crowds out private investment via interest rates.

But when the central bank controls the rate, and firms face uncertain demand, this logic fails.

Spending creates income, not competition for funds.
Read 7 tweets
Jul 28
Mainstream macro relies on rational expectations: agents are assumed to know the model and forecast the future accordingly.

But real economies aren't solved backwards.
The Deep Minsky model throws this out, and models how expectations actually evolve.
🧵1/7 Image
Instead of perfect foresight, Deep Minsky agents adapt using feedback:
-Flows inform future behavior
-Perceived trends shift confidence
-Expectations are path-dependent

This lets the model evolve historically, not jump from equilibrium to equilibrium.
🧵2/7
In Deep Minsky, investment, consumption, and pricing decisions respond to changing financial conditions, not "optimal" plans.

Expectations are formed endogenously, through firm behavior, bank leverage, and wage–price dynamics.
🧵3/7 Image
Read 7 tweets
Jul 27
In the 1960s, MIT's Jay Forrester created a simulation that changed how we think about supply chains: the Beer Game.

It revealed that even stable demand can cause wild production swings—now known as the bullwhip effect.
🧵1/10 Image
The game has 4 roles: Retailer, Wholesaler, Distributor & Factory.

Each tries to meet demand & manage inventory—but only sees demand after it’s placed. That delay leads each player to guess, and missteps quickly multiply.
🧵2/10
If the retailer slightly overorders, the wholesaler overreacts, the distributor does the same, and the factory ramps up too much. That overcorrection leads to big swings—causing stockouts or bloated inventories.
🧵3/10 Image
Read 10 tweets
Jul 25
Mainstream macro uses the NAIRU, or the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment, as a constraint.

If unemployment falls “too low,” inflation is expected to rise uncontrollably.

But this framework misrepresents both data and Phillips’ original insight.
🧵1/7 Image
In 1958, Phillips published a paper showing a statistical relationship between wage inflation and unemployment in the UK, not a structural law.

He didn’t claim there was a “natural” rate or a threshold.

It was a historical pattern, not a causal rule.
📎 Phillips (1958)
🧵2/7
Phillips warned this relationship could shift with institutions, union density, labor laws, bargaining regimes.

Modern NAIRU theory ignored that.

Instead, it imposed a fixed trade-off and turned an empirical curve into a universal policy constraint.
🧵3/7
Read 7 tweets
Sep 10, 2023
Macroeconomic Price Level Theories.

I've been trying to develop a coherent set of equations for the price level in my #systemdynamics model.

My conclusion on the matter: Its important to understand that these theories are not mutually exclusive. 🧵Thread 1/8 Current price level equations for the draft Economics Biophysical Dynamic Model.
Quantity Theory of Money (QTM):

QTM suggests that the price level is directly linked to the money supply. More money = higher prices (assuming other factors remain constant). It's a fundamental idea in monetary economics.🧵Thread 2/8 Nicolaus Copernicus
Monetarism:

Monetarists, like Milton Friedman, stress the importance of controlling the money supply growth rate to maintain stable prices. They argue that excessive money growth leads to inflation.🧵Thread 3/8 Milton Friedman
Read 8 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Don't want to be a Premium member but still want to support us?

Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal

Or Donate anonymously using crypto!

Ethereum

0xfe58350B80634f60Fa6Dc149a72b4DFbc17D341E copy

Bitcoin

3ATGMxNzCUFzxpMCHL5sWSt4DVtS8UqXpi copy

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us!

:(