Economic Naturalist Question #19. Why are dramatic political shifts so difficult to predict? #EconTwitter Image
In an earlier thread, I explored why introductory economics courses appear to leave little lasting imprint on the millions of students who take them each year:
Students learn more effectively when they pose interesting questions based on personal experience, and then use basic economic principles to help answer them. This exercise became what I call my “economic naturalist” writing assignment.
Many interesting questions are inspired by political events. After decades of stasis and with little apparent warning, political systems sometimes experience revolutionary upheaval. Why are such episodes so rare and so difficult to predict?
As the economist Timur Kuran described in his 1997 book, PRIVATE TRUTHS AND PUBLIC LIES, virtually no political experts foresaw the rapid breakup of the Soviet Union that began in the late 1980s (apart from a few who had predicted its collapse every year for many years). Image
In Kuran’s account, pundits overestimated the Soviet bloc’s stability largely because most people who lived in member countries voiced consistent support for their leaders in public opinion polls.
But because speaking out against a regime in power entailed obvious risks, polling data were not a reliable measure. Those who support a regime when a pollster asks may merely be trying to avoid those risks.
But there’s safety in numbers. The cost of speaking out depends in part on how many others are also speaking out. Some speak out no matter what, but others are willing to do so only if sufficiently many others join them.
The upshot is that even seemingly minor provocations or small changes in the odds of punishment can unleash a prairie fire of unexpected public opposition—first, by inducing a few additional people to speak out, which then induces still others to do so, and so on.
Dynamic processes like these often culminate in near complete reversals of public opinion. They explain why big changes sometimes happen so quickly and with so little forewarning.
An example: imagine a population consisting of 10 citizens—call them A, B, C, D, E, F, G, H, I, and J—who live under an authoritarian regime that they would oppose publicly if they thought it safe to do so.
Each has a threshold indicating his or her willingness to speak out as a function of how many others are speaking out. A, for example, is a radical who’s willing to speak out no matter what.
B and C are only slightly more cautious, each willing to speak out if at least 20 percent of their fellow citizens are also speaking out.
The remaining citizens have higher thresholds, as summarized in the table below. Citizen A, by assumption, will speak out irrespective of what others do. But A constitutes only 10 percent of the population, and that’s below the threshold of each of the others. Image
All but A will therefore remain silent. The stable outcome in this situation, indicated by the asterisk above the shaded entries in the table, is that only one in 10 citizens speak out. The regime survives. But now suppose something causes B to become less cautious.
Perhaps he is emboldened by news accounts describing how German dissidents suffered no consequences when they dismantled the Berlin Wall. Or perhaps he or a family member has suffered in some unexpected way from an action by the regime.
Whatever the cause, B’s threshold for speaking out falls from 20% to only 10%, as indicated below. Since A is already speaking out, B’s slightly lower new threshold is now met, so he too speaks out, in the process raising the percentage of citizens speaking out to 20. Image
This makes C willing to speak out as well, pushing the percentage to 30. E then starts speaking out, raising the percentage speaking out to 40, and so on.
In short order, a small change affecting only B causes the percentage of the population speaking out against the regime to rise from only 10 percent to 100 percent, again as indicated by the asterisk above the shaded entries in the table. This time, the regime topples.
Is the US on the cusp of dramatic political change? It feels like it. But it has felt that way before. Behavioral contagion helps explain why it is so hard to predict whether this time is different. But it also explains why change, when it happens, will happen quickly.
As I discuss in UNDER THE INFLUENCE: PUTTING PEER PRESSURE TO WORK, behavioral contagion has dramatic implications not just for the possibility of dramatic political change, but also for how to battle climate change, inequality, and viral pandemics.
amazon.com/Under-Influenc…
Ezra Klein and I discuss many of the ideas from the book in the most recent episode of his podcast, which he has entitled "Robert Frank's Radical Idea":
vox.com/podcasts/2020/…

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Robert H Frank

Robert H Frank Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @econnaturalist

25 Oct
The government says it cannot reunite the 545 children separated from their parents at the border, because it has no record of the parents' identities or whereabouts. But the parents know exactly who they are. That makes this an easy problem to solve. Image
Step one: Send saliva samples from the children to a respected international organization--Doctors Without Borders, maybe, or The Red Cross--which would then sequence the DNA of each child.
Step two: Issue a public call to parents whose children were taken from them to submit saliva samples of their own.
Read 8 tweets
19 Oct
As psychologists say, “It’s the situation, not the person.” The strongest predictor of what people will do is what others around them do. In this thread, I’ll describe what behavioral contagion theory says about how the campaign is likely to play out during the final two weeks.
First some background: During the pandemic, I’ve been participating in weekly Zoom calls with former Peace Corps Volunteers who served with me in Nepal during the late 1960s. As among so many of my other friends, there is high anxiety in this group about the election.
During our early calls, prediction markets were pegging the presidential race as a near tossup. That struck me as preposterous, and I tried to explain why. As our conversations unfolded, it gradually became my role on the call to reassure others about Biden’s prospects.
Read 19 tweets
22 Jul
As Genevieve Guenther (@DoctorVive) points out, the climate conversation has finally moved past the mindless disputes with denialists that dominated recent discussion. But we now seem stalled in the absence of a consensus about what to do next.
In the face of record wildfires and 100°F Arctic temperatures, most people now accept that we face a deadly serious challenge. Now many ask, is rapid decarbonization even feasible at any cost? And if so, is there any prospect that voters would be willing to bear that cost?
On the first question, if you’re not familiar with the work of the energy engineer Saul Griffith, I urge you to read this short piece that explains how we can decarbonize rapidly:
medium.com/otherlab-news/…
Read 9 tweets
4 Jun
Will General Mattis end up being Citizen B, whose willingness to speak out proves explosively contagious?
In a recent thread about behavioral contagion’s role in debate, I described an example involving 10 citizens—A through J—who would oppose an authoritarian regime publicly if they thought it safe to do so. Citizen B was the pivotal figure in this example.
Each has a threshold indicating her/his willingness to speak out as a function of how many others are speaking out. A, for example, is willing to speak out no matter what. B and C are more cautious, each willing to speak out only if at least 20% of others are also speaking out.
Read 11 tweets
19 May
Economic Naturalist Question #15. Why don’t top-ranked private universities charge higher tuition than many of their lower-ranked counterparts? #EconTwitter
After posing this question, my former student Lonnie Fox noted that although the ratio of applications to available slots is far higher at top-ranked universities than at their lower-ranked counterparts, tuition payments vary little across schools of different rank.
Top-ranked schools typically admit less than 10% of applicants, whereas many lower-ranked schools admit more than 50%. Expenditures per pupil are also higher at top-ranked schools. If both costs and demand are higher at top-ranked universities, why don’t they charge more?
Read 12 tweets
25 Apr
Economic Naturalist Question #2: Why do brides often spend thousands of dollars on wedding dresses they will never wear again, while grooms typically rent cheap tuxedos, even though they will have many future occasions that call for one?
Jennifer Dulski, who got married six months before she took my class in 1997, posed one of my all-time favorite responses to my Economic Naturalist writing assignment.
Asking why brides buy and grooms rent is an interesting question because it would seem that each would do better by following the other’s strategy. Why don’t brides rent and grooms buy?
Read 11 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Too expensive? Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal Become our Patreon

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us on Twitter!