A (long) thread complementing those by @Caffar3Cristina and @johnnyryan encouraging competition economists to make theories of harm based on (lack of) privacy and data protection core features of antitrust investigations from our @VoxEU article last week. voxeu.org/content/antitr…
Side note: my views have been strongly influenced by the fight alongside @Caffar3Cristina & others to have the types of harms we identify in the piece be taken seriously in the Google-Fitbit merger. The specifics of our opposition here: 2/
The focus is mostly digital platform deals and conduct. DPs are well understood by this point: they offer something consumers like (search results, email, maps, etc.) “for free.” This is the first bit of bad framing that limits effective antitrust around data. 3/
No money may change hands, but of course platforms do get paid – with our data. Usually some combination of demographic, location, and/or interest data, which they then (mostly) monetize (so far) in online advertising markets. 4/
As such, it’s time to call a firm’s policies regarding the data they collect, how they combine it with other data, how they use it, and how they sell it what it is: the *price* of using digital platform services. 5/
Framing (lack of) privacy and/or data protection as a price is far more useful than the more typical economic approach of thinking of it as a quality attribute. 6/
Why? Because in standard economics the relationship between quality and market power is generally ambiguous (e.g. see our intro here: aeaweb.org/articles?id=10…, with @MatthewShum2 & Alex Shcherbakov). 7/
But there is little ambiguity about the direction of privacy protection (down) and data collection practices (up) as ad-funded digital platforms (G&F) have become dominant (see, e.g., @DinaSrinivasan here: papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cf…). 8/
This is no surprise: we pay with data and prices rise with market power (see the UK’s CMA’s impressive online advertising market study). gov.uk/cma-cases/onli… 9/
Further complicating matters is that consumers often don’t know how their data are being used and therefore don’t even know the prices they pay (e.g. Appendix G in the CMA’s online advertising market study linked to above). 10/
The literature on “unobserved prices” finds that this can further reduce welfare as competition won’t improve outcomes on attributes consumers can’t see (See Paul Heidhues and Botond Koszegi’s survey in the Handbook of Behavioral Econ sciencedirect.com/science/articl…). 11/
Seeing (lack of) privacy and data protection as a price means mergers like Google-Fitbit that combine data are particularly bad. Not only is this an ex-post price increase for Fitbit users (whose health/wellness data can now be monetized by Google)… 12/
…..but also it is an ex-post price increase for users of Google’s services (whose demographic/location/interest data can now be monetized in health markets). 13/
Who knew that this is what you were signing up for when you chose to use Gmail, download Chrome, or bought an Android phone (or bought a Fitbit)??? 14/
It’s time to treat data collection and use as the price increases that they are and make them a core part of the harms to be prevented in investigations of deals or dominant firm conduct. How? 15/
First, learn what data is collected and how it used/sold now and, if part of a deal, how data sources will be combined in future. Internal documents/investor presentations/similar can be helpful here. 16/
Second, measure consumer tastes for these uses (e.g. privpapers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cf…). Yes, survey methods have their flaws, but conventional methods don’t work when prices are unobserved. 17/
These are the prices/price changes from the conduct/transaction. If enforcers/their economists are willing to push beyond the conventional wisdom, they can serve as a basis for merger conditions involving purpose limitations or a block. 18/
A second thread that we argue competition economists should pick up is that lack of privacy and data protection can facilitate exploitation and foreclosure. 19/
Data often creates markets with increasing returns to scale, causing them to tip to a dominant firm. It also allows personalized offers, and if paired with dominance this creates discriminatory power and thus the potential for exploitation. 20/
Data is also general-purpose input, inducing complementarities that can be exploited by all the regular “tricks” of dominant firms seeking to extend their market power and foreclose rivals (e.g. tying, bundling, restrictive contracting, etc.). 21/
In Google-Fitbit, both exploitation and foreclosure concerns were present. Because Google is dominant in non-health data, allowing them to combine it with health and wellness data implies a significant risk of exploitation in insurance and other “health-tech” markets. 22/
Similarly, @ProfFionasm and @DavidDinielli (from p25) argue Facebook foreclosed competitors by deceptively tracking users while claiming in its privacy policies that it wasn’t (based on @DinaSrinivasan's work above). 23/ omidyar.com/news/roadmap-f…
Motivated by Google-Fitbit, Chen, Choo, Cong, and Matsushima (2020) analyze “data-driven mergers,” showing that personalization can lead to exploitation and the leveraging of market power.
ideas.repec.org/p/dpr/wpaper/1…. 24/
Indeed, there is a growing academic literature on harms from data, e.g. “privacy policy tying,” “privacy externalities,” and more; it’s time for competition economists to take these on board and also make them a central part of investigations.
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cf…
25/
Privacy experts have been way ahead of competition economists on consumer harms from digital platform data collection and exploitation; it’s time we listened and worked to bring their concerns into our models and data-related cases. END/

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Gregory Crawford

Gregory Crawford Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @GregorySCrawfor

6 Jan
This is a great analysis by @Caffar3Cristina and @ProfFionasm of the strengths and weaknesses of the EC's (first draft) Digital Markets Act. There is a lot here worth promoting, so a short thread summarizing/emphasizing on the parts I liked most.
voxeu.org/article/europe…
First, a discussion of the organizing principles of the DMA: not old-fashioned utility (price/access) regulation, but to promote entry and encourage fairness.
Second, a *very* useful mapping of (a) gatekeeper defns & (b) proscribed behavior into targets: obv GAFAM, but also Oracle & SAP [intentional?], w/ others meeting some but not all thresholds (Booking, Spotify, Uber). Lots of links in the f/notes to justify their decisions.
Read 7 tweets
22 Dec 20
The ACCC rejected the insufficient conditions w/ which DG Comp cleared Google-Fitbit. The EC decision shows a lack of courage and a refusal to learn from past mistakes. Having worked for months w/ @Caffar3Cristina trying to explain why, it’s time to put down a final marker. 1/
This is a (long) thread in four parts:

I.The Problem with Google
II.Google-Fitbit in a time of Digital Platform introspection
III.Google-Fitbit Theories of Harm
IV.The remedies are insufficient

2/
PART I: The Problem with Google.

We’ll start by agreeing that Google makes some great products. (That’s not the problem.) It claims: 3/
Read 49 tweets
27 Aug 20
A few thoughts on (1) the @acccgovau bargaining code to encourage G/F compensation for news and (2) its potential for “Decentralized Regulation” for dominant DPs generally, written with @Caffar3Cristina. A thread summarizing the post for the TLDR crowd. 1/ voxeu.org/article/accc-s…
(Part 0/Context:) The premise is that regulation for dominant digital platforms is coming (e.g. the UK and EC are advancing legislative proposals). What should these address? How should they be designed? 2/
Re: what to address, most of the focus of international antitrust enforcement re: DPs has been on exclusion (e.g. the EC’s Google cases), but there is a burgeoning interest on exploitation and expropriation of value. 3/
Read 16 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Too expensive? Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal Become our Patreon

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us on Twitter!