In "Nudge", @R_Thaler and @CassSunstein often argue that neoclassical economics assumes that humans behave as if they're Mr Spock, while, in reality, we behave more like Homer Simpson. There's an implicit assumption in this analogy that Mr Spock is the normative reference/
point : deviations from the Spock standards are suboptimal, and what they call "libertarian paternalism" should nudge people towards the choices they would make if only they were more like Spock. But @juliagalef beautifully illustrates why Spockism is not the right standard for /
rationality when you're not facing fellow Spockians. There are beautiful examples of this in experimental game theory. Consider the game where you have to state a number, and the winner is the person whose number is closest to half of the average guess. How would you play? /
(Oh, I forgot that the number had to be between zero and 100)
Now take your time to think how you would play the game if you were Spock facing other Spocks. And then how you would play it if you would face normal humans (no need to go as low as Homer Simpson). Come on, try it/
OK, let's follow the Spockian approach first. Given that the maximum number is 100, half of the average value of the other guesses can never be strictly larger than 50. So it is irrational to propose a number larger than 50. But if this is the case (and the other players/
are rational), then half of the average value of the other guesses can never be larger than 25. It is therefore irrational to propose any number than 25. OK, by now you should see where we are heading: the only strategy that survives the iterated elimination of dominated/
strategies is to propose zero. If everyone is Spock, the only possible outcome is a tie. But is this the best way to play in real life?
Well, economists have been running experiments where participants could play the game - with real money at stake, to be sure they face the correct incentives. The one I am best aware of, was run with CalTech students - as you know from "The big bang theory", the closest/
you get to Spock in real life. (More seriously, these are among the smartest people on earth, so if anyone should play the game rationally, they should). What was the outcome? Well, almost no one got further than the second or third round in the iterative process I /
described above. So not only did they did play the Spockian approach, but playing the Spockian approach would be the surest way to lose the game, systematically. And, remember, these people are smart as hell. So the key lesson here: being Spock should not be the standard for/
rational behaviour, because Spock simply does not have a useful model of human behaviour. By the way, this is directly relevant of course for what is currently going on around Ukraine. Even if everyone's objectives were clear (they are not) and even if /
the evaluation of the balance of forces were straightforward (it is not), it would be an error to assume Spockian behaviour. In the coming days, decisions will be made under incredible stress, decision makers will face the risk of losing face, etc etc. The late Thomas/
Shelling had lots of interesting points on this.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
Hidden within the @ITF_Forum report on #micromobility "30 km/h is the maximum limit recommended for cars in city streets to reduce the risk of death or serious injury from a collision of cars with pedestrians and other vulnerable road users."
On the topic of shared micromobility itself: "Shared micromobility predominantly replaces walking, cycling and public transport trips yet could also substitute short car trips. The broadest benefit ...could be increasing
the catchment area of public transport. " /
"Their widespread availability, particularly for first/last-mile connections, could improve access while shortening commuting time and reducing reliance on cars. However, micromobility ... raise concerns of nuisance on sidewalks, the safety of users and pedestrians" /
The best point yet I read in @HansRosling 's "Factfulness": in the past, people did not live in balance with nature. They *died* in balance with nature. As Hobbes already knew, live was short, nasty and cruel. /
I quite often say that books are highly recommended, but "Factfulness" is a must read in the most literal sense of the word: it should be put on the school curriculum. Not just because it sets so many things straight about the world, but because it is one big argument in /
favour of a data rather than impressions based approach to understanding the world. If the data tell you that your priors are demonstrably false, you need to update your priors. Also, it is a good guide to the mental biases that guide our /
In case you wonder, The Code is a history of Silicon Valley. And it's really good if you're interested in innovation and innovation policy. Of course, it doesn't replace academic work on those topics, but, besides being entertaining, it also /
brings together a lot of important facts that are forgotten. The crucial role of defence spending in kickstarting the Valley is known - what is less obvious, is that defence industry only came there because the American top brass was worried that a Soviet first strike /
might wipe out the defence industry in southern California. Contingency and path dependency matter. Also, the first generations of Silicon Valley entrepreneurs were not exactly hippies, but conservative men in white shirts and ties. And venture capitalists usually had very/
Leuk opinie artikel. Als ik nu de "Blake en Mortimers" uit mijn kinderjaren herlees, zie ik ook wel hoe stereotypisch en "fout" het allemaal is. Maar ik heb "Indiër" echt nooit geassocieerd met een "trouwe dienaar" die mij als "Sahib" aanspreekt. Ook zonder sticker. /