My charts on the distribution of real wage growth were flat out wrong, as @IrvingSwisher correctly pointed out. I'm deleting all of the tweets (here's a screenshot of one so you know what I'm talking about). Feel terrible to have put this out.
This 🧵 explains more fully.
The question I was trying to ask was what has happened to wage growth adjusted for inflation by different income groups & how does it compare to pre-COVID.
The broad inference is likely still true but possibly less bad than I showed (it is unclear). The data was wrong.
I still believe the following are true for the period from the pandemic to today:
1. On average nominal wages have increased more slowly than inflation.
2. Faster wage gains for lower-wage workers
3. For most groups any inflation-adjusted gains are smaller than pre-pandemic.
It is also likely that the bottom quartile has (on average) seen real wage gains and that the top quartile has (on average) seen real wage losses.
I do not have a confident view about what has happened to the middle quartiles. And I'm not sure the data can answer the question.
Let me reiterate: I've shown real wage losses for the two middle quartiles. A lot of people noticed that and cared because, if true, it's a big deal. I do not know if that was true or not anymore.
OK, now to explain the error. The Atlanta Fed Wage Tracker provides nominal wage data w/ various breakdowns. I've mostly used their wage growth by quartile. They match the same workers who were employed 12 months apart to address compositional changes.
When they do the breakdowns of the data the sample size gets very small so what they call "12 month growth" is actually a moving average of the last 12 12 month growth rates. This is effectively a moving average of a moving average of monthly growth rates.
In my effort to show real wage changes I paired it with CPI growth measured between two points in time. So my CPI growth was completely mismatched to the wage growth. That is flat out wrong and a dumb thing to do.
You might think the way to correct this would be to use the same moving average of a moving average for CPI. That would, indeed, give you a coherent answer. This is what that chart looks like. Unfortunately it is not an answer to the question anyone cares about.
The question I was asking is what happened to wages and prices from January 2020 to January 2022, ie during the pandemic and the economic recovery from it.
The chart is internally consistent but doesn't answer that question, in fact it doesn't answer any relevant question.
Specifically, the question one wants is the sum of the last 24 monthly growth rates.
The internally consistent chart de facto draws 27% of its growth from the pre-pandemic period (should be 0%) and only 27% from the last year (should be 50%).
(I might post a technical thread on that later because it's fun, is analogous to the issues with annual average growth vs. Q4/Q4 growth I've written about before.)
The Atlanta Fed does not publish the data to look just at January 2020 to January 2022 but you can run the programs they provide to get it. The problem is the data is really volatile (why they smooth it) so the answers change a decent amount from month to month.
Every chart in the previous tweet is correct (I hope!). They all tell a broadly similar story (the one I listed above). But they differ a lot from each other, especially in the middle two quartiles). That could reflect true changes but almost certainly reflects data noise.
Thanks to Twitter I've also learned about other ways that the Atlanta Fed Wage Tracker, while excellent, may have limits in answering these questions, especially at such a strange time. These include mean reversion, age composition, etc.
All data has its limits, one does the best one can. One way is also to compare to other data. In particular, I (and many others) find the officially published ECI data to be among the most accurate in dealing with composition.
Here is the growth of real wages by occupations for the pandemic period compared to pre-pandemic ranked by wages.
You can see real wages up at the bottom, down at the top, and generally doing worse than pre-pandemic.
Increases my confidence in the broad story.
I genuinely appreciate @IrvingSwisher letting me know and giving me time to figure this out--we sometimes agree and sometimes disagree on the economics but I'll never make the mistake of arguing data with him again.
Apologies for the error and (yet another) long thread.
A technical footnote to the thread from yesterday.
A thread on the perils of interpreting moving averages that will be of interest to almost no one. Also has implications for annual averages which is a slightly more important topic. This fleshes out one aspect of my error with the Atlanta Fed wage data.
I'll use a made up hypothetical of the following wage data. What would you say happened to wages in the pandemic period (which for expositional simplicity I'm drawing as starting in 2020)?
I think you would say wages fell in the pandemic.
The right calculation for what happened in wages in the pandemic would be:
Wage growth in pandemic = (wage level Dec 2021 / wage level Dec 2019).
In the picture above this is -1% if you annualize (take the square root to get growth per year).
Even if all firms are perfectly competitive an increase in demand will result in an increase in profits in the "short run"--the short run being a potentially long period until new entrants can compete the profits away.
A 🧵 with an refresher/explainer on the Ec10 of this.
The left-hand curves are the normal supply & demand, they show the market as a whole. The supply curve is the sum of the products supplied by many, many firms. Demand increases for some reason (a taste shift, strong economy, stimulus checks, whatever). The result is P and Q up.
The right-hand curves are from the perspective of a single firm. It is just a small firm in a big competitive market with no pricing power so it "sees" a horizontal demand curve. It can sell it wants at that price but nothing if it raises the price a penny above it.
If you think corporate greed is playing a major role in the current inflation then you need to rethink a lot of your views.
1. FISCAL MULTIPLIERS. Fiscal stimulus is less effective than you thought because it will go more into prices/profits than quantities.
2. INCIDENCE ANALYSIS OF FISCAL TRANSFERS. Distributional tables that show the stimulus checks going to households, for example, not correctly reflect that much of the benefit of the stimulus checks was captured by higher prices instead of higher purchasing power.
3. WORKER POWER AND REAL WAGES. If stronger demand raised the ability of corporations to do unfair or unjustified price increases over and above their costs then the flip side is you are saying that heating the economy lowers real wages.
Some fun new pictures in the new version, like what a standard set of rules of thumb (multipliers, Okun's law, Phillips curve) would have predicted. Which would have been a completely batty forecast.
A way to think about inflation: it has a permanent component and a transitory component.
Use CPI signal extraction (e.g., look at subsets of the CPI) to understand the dynamics of transitory.
But use structural macro thinking to predict trajectory of permanent.
Very short 🧵
The best way to understand the TRANSITORY part is to get deep inside the CPI data & also listen to Odd Lots with @tracyalloway and @TheStalwart.
Thinking about statistical mean reversion, understanding which parts of the CPI are signal and which are noise, etc., works OK here.
To understand the PERMANENT part you should look a little at the CPI data. But mostly think about forward-looking macro models not CPI signal extraction. Eg, labor markets tighter than they were a year ago, inflation expectations higher, monetary policy still ultra accommodative.
1. The Fed needs to hike in March. If two strong jobs reports & another high inflation print should be 50bp. But 25 bp is OK too as long as they're on an every meeting pace.
2. Congress needs to raise the Child Tax Credit.
The truth is the President can do very little to lower inflation. He can & should do everything he can on supply (and he is doing most of it already) but won't add up to much.
Congress *could* lower inflation with contractionary fiscal policy but I would leave it to the Fed.
What Congress and the President could do is pass something like Build Back Better that provides more relief from these rising prices.
And it would not further add to the price increases if it is paid for.
Throw in a little deficit reduction as insurance if you want.