This resolves one international tax mystery, but raises another set of questions.

It turns out that *France* proposed the trivially low 12.5% rate for a global minimum corporate tax... 🧵
It has long been something of a mystery why the OECD secretariat pushed 12.5% in the 'pillar 2' discussions.

One theory went like this.
The secretariat were committed, or saw the commitment of some major member states, to keep pillars 1 and 2 together. But pillar 1 (as the secretariat proposed it) needed treaty change, meaning Ireland etc could block. So to minimise that risk, pillar 2 had to be 'acceptable'...
...and for pillar 2 to be acceptable to Ireland, this theory went, the minimum rate could not exceed Ireland's statutory rate: 12.5%.
It doesn't really make sense though. Profit shifting to Ireland (and equally to Netherlands, Lux, etc) doesn't depend on the statutory rate - but on the effective rates that are actually achievable, which are much nearer zero.
And so there's no real reason for corporate tax havens to be bothered about a rate of 12.5% in particular - if a global minimum tax was effective, even 12.5% would dramatically increase what was being paid by their profit shifting clientele.
So it makes sense now that to hear that it was France proposing the very low 12.5% rate. This wasn't about a strategy to keep havens on board, but - it seems - about the resistance of a major OECD member to higher effective rates on (their) multinationals.
And it also follows - given all that we've heard from lower-income countries in the 'Inclusive' Framework, about how their voices are simply ignored - that the secretariat would have responded on this point not to Ireland etc, but to their own host country and G7 member, France.
This sheds some light on another small mystery too.

US intervention has likely saved the OECD process from an ignominious end, after missing the 2020 deadline, and with most OECD members unenthusiastic (complex proposals, small projected revenues). And yet...
And yet: we hear voices talking about much lower rates (15%-18%) than the 21% Yellen+Biden propose; and we hear arguments that the global minimum tax should not be a revenue-raiser (that being the 'mandate' for pillar 1 instead).
This all makes sense, if we (1) read the negotiations as a G7 internal issue, not a wider OECD one; and (2) see France, Germany and perhaps others not as 'committed to progress but thwarted by Trump', but instead lukewarm only about making serious improvements to corporate tax.
OK, if that adds a little clarity to our understanding of the negotiations, the question as ever is: Where do things go from here?
There are two main issues to consider. First, what if anything can be delivered (effectively, by the G7) within the current OECD/G20 process? And second, what happens to international tax rule-setting after that?
On the first question, I wrote a bit here: taxjustice.net/2021/04/08/300…

Most of this stands, but we can go a bit further now...
You can stick a fork in Pillar 1, it's done. There is zero prospect of anything that delivers on the original ambition of going 'beyond the arm's length principle'.
Three possibilities for pillar 1:
i. nothing delivered at all
ii. something so narrow that barely any of the global profit of multinationals is affected
iii. something closer to the OECD proposal, requiring treaty change, which is never really delivered
With questions raised over whether the Biden proposal (to focus on 100 multinationals only) would capture some of the most high profile companies, notably Amazon, this starts to look a difficult sell. But equally, the OECD proposal has few supporters, hence the process stalling.
The Biden proposal has the attraction that it can be delivered by firm-specific agreements that don't require treaty change, so you could say that you're going to do it, and then see if much of anything happens. And that might free up space for agreement on pillar 2...
On pillar 2, there are two major issues to resolve: what rate, for a global minimum effective tax rate; and who gets to tax the undertaxed profits that are identified?

The answers to these are critical to everything else. This *could be* an unprecedented step forward; or not.
On the rate: agreement on 21% (or higher - e.g. @ICRICT recommends 25%+) would be dramatic. This could raise, under the OECD approach, some $540bn in additional annual revenues, the great majority of which would go to OECD member countries.
On the distribution of the rights to tax the undertaxed profits: the OECD approach privileges headquarters countries, including US, over host countries, so most lower-income countries get very little in comparison.
Apart from being demonstrably unjust, this may also conflict with the intention of the Biden administration - who are proposing to change the US rules in a way that facilitates a different approach to headquarters vs host countries.
The alternative is our METR proposal - which follows great technical work of the OECD secretariat to identify undertaxed profits, & then taps original spirit of pillar 1 and apportions the undertaxed profit according to the location of real activity (sales and employment).
The result is that the METR with 21% rate would raise a projected $640bn a year: a bit more for OECD countries, and much more for lower-income countries - towards an additional 30%-40% of CIT revenues for both groups on average.

More on the METR: taxjustice.net/2021/04/15/the…
Where will the G7 come down on these issues? The UK is chairing this year, and has so far refused to offer any great support for the Biden proposals. France and others in the EU, per the above, may not be enthusiastic on a major reform, despite previous noises.
Set against that, the Biden administration is highly and publicly committed, including as part of the domestically-aimed package of its 'Made in America tax plan'; and still in its honeymoon period, with others keen to make friends and catch a little of the halo.
The OECD secretariat really needs an outcome, in light of the existing delay and the growing pressures it faces. These relate to concerns that it has been unable to generate proposals that would yield the necessary scale of progress - and pandemic-appropriate revenues...
...coupled with concerns over the incoming new leadership (Australia's Mathias Cormann, with a track record on both tax and climate in which the word 'denial' features more often than the organisation might like)...
...and the growing momentum to shift international tax rule-setting to a globally inclusive setting at the United Nations
taxjustice.net/2021/02/25/a-t…
Which brings us nicely, and finally, to the last issue: what will happen *after* the OECD delivers a deal, or doesn't, at the June G7/July G20 meetings?
Consider three scenarios:
i. Globally beneficial success! (High minimum tax rate, with benefits shared fairly under METR proposal or similar)
ii. Narrow deal, limited benefits outside G7/OECD members
iii. No deal
In the first of these, you could really make an argument that the OECD had delivered. The scale of additional revenues, and the full inclusion of lower-income countries outside the OECD, would make a powerful argument that the global architecture is working.
In the second and third scenarios, where the OECD either doesn't deliver at all or doesn't deliver very much, and especially not for non-members, the added momentum to shift the rule-setting power away from the club of rich countries may quickly become irresistible.
That could go two ways. Enough OECD members could share the disillusionment that they stop blocking the start of negotiations on a UN tax convention - which would set ambitious transparency and cooperation standards, and also set a basis for intergovernmental negotiation at UN.
Or OECD members could continue their current blocking of UN progress, and effectively commit the world to a sustained period of unilateral mechanisms (far beyond DSTs), and the further splintering of tax rules for multinationals worldwide.
The fact that senior OECD figures have been quite public recently in their attacks on the UN is a reflection of the pressures the organisation faces. And on balance, it's a good thing - this is one of the defining arguments about global tax justice, and it needs to happen openly.
The OECD can argue that things move slowly at the UN - but that's harder to sustain when the UN tax committee has just delivered a treaty article on tax and digitalisation, before the OECD and despite OECD members trying to block it.
The OECD can argue, as they did on an @FT panel with @EmmaAgyemang, that the transparency of government positions in the UN would 'kill negotiations'. But that does highlight the OECD's own opacity, and is clearly not supported by the success of UN negotiations on e.g. climate.
The more that OECD opposes in public, the more people may be reminded that the UN was basically created in order to negotiate tricky issues where all countries of the world may have a stake, and different opinions, and where citizens care about government positions. Tax, anyone?
But at the same time, the power of OECD members is near total. If the Biden administration were to oppose any UN progress, that would probably be it - on top of the leading opposition now of UK, Switzerland, Liechtenstein (seriously). But would they?
Biden has pledged to lead the global fight against illicit finance, as well as to reverse the race to the bottom on corporate tax; and of course to re-establish the US as a committed multilateralist. If it became clear the OECD couldn't deliver, and the UN sought to, what then?
Apologies for the long thread - there's a lot moving right now! From now til July, all on eyes on what G7 negotiates and G20/OECD agree - and then perhaps to the UN...

• • •

Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to force a refresh
 

Keep Current with Alex Cobham

Alex Cobham Profile picture

Stay in touch and get notified when new unrolls are available from this author!

Read all threads

This Thread may be Removed Anytime!

PDF

Twitter may remove this content at anytime! Save it as PDF for later use!

Try unrolling a thread yourself!

how to unroll video
  1. Follow @ThreadReaderApp to mention us!

  2. From a Twitter thread mention us with a keyword "unroll"
@threadreaderapp unroll

Practice here first or read more on our help page!

More from @alexcobham

4 Dec 20
History faces forwards as well as backwards. As we prepare for the second day of our #ImperialInequalities conference today, and our new @FPCThinkTank
piece is published, I've blogged on whether and how the UK could move beyond its imperial legacies
taxjustice.net/2020/12/04/the…
Registration for day 2 of #ImperialInequalities is still open, and the events get underway in just over three hours
Dr Ndongo Samba Sylla @nssylla opens day 2 of #ImperialInequalities, with a keynote on 'Colonial macroeconomics: Then and now' in which he highlights the commonality between imperial approaches and contemporary economic policies
Read 23 tweets
3 Dec 20
We're now starting the first panel of our #ImperialInequalities conference, with @JuliaMcClure_ examining the role of 'welfare imperialism' in the Spanish empire.

>150 people viewing live, join them below!
Here's the full first panel #ImperialInequalities, with @JuliaMcClure_ (U. Glasgow) David Brown (Trinity) @madeline_woker (Brown U.) & Laura Channing (Cambridge) and moderated by @GKBhambra
At #ImperialInequalities, @JuliaMcClure_ highlights how ideas of 'charity' and 'welfare' were central to justifications for empire; and also created opportunities for private individuals to capture benefits, including through the abuse of charitable foundations to hold wealth
Read 21 tweets
6 Nov 20
This is fantastic - really impressive set of questions and issues raised on the international approach to illicit financial flows. There's a lot to say so I'll thread the replies here, bit by bit...
1. Why did the MDGs overlook non-aid finance? This was by design: the MDGs were driven by aid donors, and were largely conceived of as ensuring better alignment of donors and recipient states - setting common goals so aid would deliver more.
Here's Sakiko Fukuda-Parr on this point - whereas by 2015, the aid focus was widely understood as a central flaw in the MDGs, so the aim of the Sustainable Development Goals was to ensure much broader ownership & applying to countries at all income levels
researchgate.net/publication/29… Image
Read 57 tweets
20 Oct 20
Matt summarises very well the broadly non-ideological objections to what has just been achieved, in confirming corporate tax abuse as part of the illicit financial flows SDG target, so I'll try to thread a response with each of his points
So first, I don't think there really is much of this confusion around. People largely understand these are quite different phenomena; but they also recognise, rightly, that they depend on being hidden, and they do the same kinds of revenue & social damage
This is a point of disagreement. I saw that much of the pushback was *precisely* not to have corporate tax abuse addressed under either 16.4 *or* 17.1, but to keep it out of the SDGs entirely - on the grounds that the OECD had it covered. (Discuss.)
Read 10 tweets
20 Oct 20
It's not every day that a niche question of statistical definition represents a significant step forward for global policy. But today... is that day!

(Excessively long thread follows)
A little background. Since the Millennium Development Goals overlooked non-aid finance, pressure has been building to recognise the centrality of tax, and for global policy measures against the broad threat posed by 'illicit financial flows'...
Illicit financial flows, or IFF, is an umbrella term for cross-border capital movements covering corporate and individual tax abuse, the laundering of the proceeds of crime, abuses of market regulation, and the theft of state assets, first popularised by @Raymond_Baker
Read 22 tweets
7 Oct 20
Here's a short thread with some *stark* numbers, showing just how limited the OECD 'BEPS 2.0' tax reform proposals have become.

The secretariat proposals are at the G20 now, and published next week... so how big a deal would they be?
The numbers relate to the Netherlands, one of the biggest corporate tax havens worldwide, and part of what we've called the 'axis of tax avoidance'.
For context, here are the key parts of our previous analyses. First, a paper with @icrict last year looked at the potential impact of the reform proposals at that stage - how much would they redistribute profits, and revenues, from tax havens? osf.io/preprints/soca…
Read 20 tweets

Did Thread Reader help you today?

Support us! We are indie developers!


This site is made by just two indie developers on a laptop doing marketing, support and development! Read more about the story.

Become a Premium Member ($3/month or $30/year) and get exclusive features!

Become Premium

Too expensive? Make a small donation by buying us coffee ($5) or help with server cost ($10)

Donate via Paypal Become our Patreon

Thank you for your support!

Follow Us on Twitter!