#Intellectualproperty--patents, copyrights, and other government-granted and -enforced monopoly privileges--gets a lot of knee-jerk support. While people invent plenty of arguments in favor, they are, unfortunately, often based in economic misunderstanding. Let's talk about #IP.
First, arguments in favor tend to rely on a cost-based theory of value. But something is not of value because it was expensive to make, but is expensive to make because it is expected to be of great value: it is the expected value that justifies taking on the (production) cost.
It's a flawed argument to ask "who would take on the great cost" to come up with new inventions if they can't get paid. Nobody has a right to get paid based on their cost or effort. You don't earn a high grade because of your effort, but put in the effort to earn a high grade.
The world contradicts the assumption in the argument: we strive to achieve value and can, because we expect/imagine/hope the result will be of value, justify taking on costs to get there. But not higher cost than we believe the outcome is worth it. This is important to remember.
Second, ideas have no value. We must make the important distinction between invention (the idea) and innovation (the realization/implementation of it, including bringing something to market). No idea matters much unless it is made useful somehow. Just the idea is but a thought.
It's commonly presumed that entrepreneurship is about having a grand idea. It's not. It's all implementation. Experienced entrepreneurs and investors know this. A mediocre idea with great implementation can change the world; a great idea with mediocre implementation is worthless.
Third, it's not as easy as "more is better." There is such a thing as over-investment in research, invention, and innovation, which means too much resources are invested in these activities compared to, for example, satisfying wants in the present. There is always a tradeoff.
In a world where everything existed in abundance, then investing endless amounts into space exploration would be no problem because there is no downside. But if it would happen at the cost of, say, feeding people, providing shelter for the homeless, or curing cancer...?
The issue is fundamentally an economic one: the economizing of resources to produce the means for want satisfaction. This is why the expected benefit must be compared to other benefits (opportunity cost). In other words, more invention comes at the expense of something else.
It's also often asserted that IP is necessary because without it there would be no invention (or at any rate "less" or "too little" of it). Yes, indeed, without subsidies (which IP amounts to) there would be less. The real question is: of what? And further: is that a bad thing?
Let's look at specific distortions, which IP contributes to (and use patents as example). As the patent holder gets the exclusive right to the idea, investments shift from innovations to inventions. So the firm is better off patenting a lot and early using a shotgun approach.
It's not only about having the idea, but if your securing a patent for it means others cannot use it, you also protect yourself from (potential) competition. Patents become a way of holding others down, at the expense of consumers who might never see products based on the ideas.
Ceteris paribus, patents lead to more inventions and, relatively speaking, fewer innovations. Are ideas not good? Sure, but not if they are produced at the expense of actual goods and services. Ideas in themselves have very little (if any) value unless they are made usable.
Everything isn't patentable, which means a lot of ideas fall outside of such protection. The incentive is therefore to do research specifically on those things that are patentable. So, we get more of what patents protect and less of what they do not protect.
To say that we get "more" is tongue in cheek. Firms invest enormous amounts into legal services because of patents. Those resources could be used in innovation instead. Add to this the waste of anti-competitor patenting. Distortions abound and consumers pay the price.
It's also claimed that patents help the little guy. That's a fiction. Large firms invest huge amounts into getting/protecting patents. Patent trolls make money this way; other firms use it strategically to squash competition. The little guy can't afford playing this game.
Many other things can be said too, but if we clear the discussion of the misunderstandings and then discuss the distortions caused by this type of system, we'll have a much better discussion. And, I think, a different consensus.
• • •
Missing some Tweet in this thread? You can try to
force a refresh
An endless source of miscommunication and misunderstanding is the use of ambiguous terms and, worse, reliance on definitions that aren't clarifying but rather the opposite. One such term is the #State. We all "know" what it is but very few have attempted to define it clearly.
For everyday purposes, we don't need to clarify the term because our intersubjective understanding of it, and how we use it (the context), makes it clear enough. But not so when we debate or try to uncover why we have different opinions about it and, especially, its nature.
The State is an organization but not like any other. It has a distinct nature, characteristics that make it different from firms, HOAs, and sports clubs. It's also not, simply but vaguely, an abstraction of some conception of "us," as many prefer to see it. So, what is the State?
If we truly want to change things for the better and contribute to a better community and society, then we should judge charitable acts based on their outcomes (the good expected or brought about), not the personal sacrifice of carrying out the act (what the doer gives up).
Many would consider a highly paid, and therefore also productive, individual spending a full day laboring in a soup kitchen a greater charity than if they had donated the money they would have earned. This conclusion requires focusing on the sacrifice, not the good brought about.
Say this individual would have earned $1,500 in their day job ($390k/year) had s/he not worked in the soup kitchen. This income is the sacrifice (cost). But the sacrifice says nothing about the good brought about by laboring in the soup kitchen.
Just putting this out there. My book from 2016 on how to properly understand the economy as a market process and the real impact of #regulations. Here's the publisher's page. (1/4) rowman.com/ISBN/978073919…
The lowest price is available from the @mises Institute bookstore. Paperback for $39.95. Additional discount for members. (2/4) store.mises.org/The-Seen-the-U…
Amazon has it available as hardcover, paperback, and Kindle, for both purchase (new and used) and rent. (3/4) amazon.com/Seen-Unseen-Un…
If we realize the value problem, we also realize the real problem that #entrepreneurs face and must find a solution to. It's not to come up with The Idea, as is often assumed, nor the invention or the technology, but how to make something valuable to other people.
Value is the experience of satisfying a want, which means to find oneself in a better situation than before and compared to what one otherwise expected. This does not need specific inputs, but if it doesn't then there is nothing stopping us from simply satisfying it at whim.
The world's limited resources means we must try to get as valuable experiences as possible, to be as well off as we can, from what means are available to us. There is no end to how content we can imagine becoming, but the means are not enough to get us there. So we must choose.
A short thread on critical thinking. To be critical is not to be contrarian, opposed, or anti--it's to be open for the possibility that you might have gotten it wrong. So, the more time/effort you've spend thinking critically about something, the more errors you'd have discarded.
That's where an 'expert' should be: they have, ideally, spent a lot of time studying some phenomenon and know a lot about it. So they would have already discarded plenty of false explanations. Unfortunately, getting an advanced degree doesn't automatically provide such expertise.
In other words: you should not accept someone's authority on a subject because of their titles/degrees. So, when I say something about the economy (my expertise), you should, if you disagree, push back, ask penetrating questions. It's likely that one of us got something wrong.
The problem with #politics is that it exaggerates and makes (empty) slogans out of what we know. This applies to the #minimumwage too, where proponents of increasing it claim it will raise people's wages and opponents claim it will kill jobs. Neither is very accurate or finds
support in economic theory. Let's look at what a minimum wage law does, and then at what we can expect from it. Because the former is rarely admitted and the latter goes both ways. So, first, a minimum wage law is not an increase in anybody's wage, it is only a prohibition of
paying employees less than a stated amount. Raising the minimum wage law does not mean whoever is making less gets an automatic raise. What it does mean, especially after a transition period, is that there will be no jobs that create less value than is necessary for employers to