When a superdense, concentrated mass forms a black hole, the laws of physics around it change, giving rise to an eldritch zone where the normal rules don't apply. When corporations form a concentrated industry, the laws of economics likewise change. 1/
If you'd like an essay-formatted version of this thread to read or share, here's a link to it on pluralistic.net, my surveillance-free, ad-free, tracker-free blog:
Take copyright: when I was a baby writer, there were dozens of comparably sized New York publishers. The writers who mentored me could shop their rights around to lots of houses, which enabled them to subdivide those rights. 3/
For example, they could separately sell paperback and hardcover rights, getting paid twice for the same book. 4/
Under those circumstances, giving authors broader copyrights and easier enforcement systems could directly translate into more groceries on those authors' tables and more gas in their cars' tanks. 5/
But today, publishing has dwindled to five giant houses (possibly four soon, depending on whether Penguin Random House successfully appeals its blocked merger with Simon and Schuster). 6/
Under these conditions, giving exploited authors more copyright is like giving bullied schoolkids more lunch-money. 7/
Whatever copyright authors get will be non-negotiably extracted from them via the near-identical, unviolable core contracting terms from the Big Five publisher. Today, the bullies don't just take your paperback rights, they also acquire your audio and ebook rights. 8/
Most of them now want your *worldwide* English rights, so you can't resell the book in the Commonwealth, and some have started demanding graphic novel, film and TV rights. 9/
In our new book, @rgibli and I call this "chokepoint capitalism". In today's highly concentrated creative labor markets, copyright's normal role of giving creators bargaining leverage over their supply chain is transformed.
Instead of being a tool for creators, copyright is inevitably transferred to part of the supply chain - a publisher, label, streamer, ebook retailers, etc - where it becomes a tool to beat up on the rest of the supply chain, *especially* creators. 11/
But copyright isn't the only policy that breaks down at the event horizon of monopoly's black hole. *Policy itself* breaks down, too. 12/
When power is pluralized among lots of firms an expert regulator can ask a technical question like "Does net neutrality lead to a decrease in private infrastructure investment?" and get *lots* of answers. 13/
Some companies - cable operators hoping to override your choices about which data you want by slowing down traffic from sites unless they pay bribes - will insist that they can't afford to build fiber without this incentive. 14/
Others - ISPs who want to raid the cable operators' customer base by giving you the data you request as fast as they can - will answer this charge. 15/
Both will provide supposedly empirical about their investment choices and capital and running costs, and both will vigorously probe the others' submissions for factual weaknesses. 16/
But when all the ISPS in your country has been monopolized so that nearly all Americans have little or no choice, regulation's truth-seeking exercise becomes an auction, with monopolists bidding together to bend reality (or regulation) to their will:
This is called #RegulatoryCapture: when there are four or five companies running an industry, nearly everyone qualified to understand it is an executive at one of those companies. Obama's "good" FCC chair was a cable lobbyist, Trump's "bad" chair was a Verizon lawyer. 18/
Ironically, the term "regulatory capture" originated with right-wing, anti-regulation nihilists. They argued capture was *inevitable* and to preserve competition we must *eliminate regulation*, including the regulations blocking monopoly formation:
Eliminating anti-monopoly rules had the entirely predictable effect of producing *lots* of monopolies. Today, nearly every global industry - beer, shipping, banking, concert tickets, eyeglasses, etc - is dominated by a handful of firms:
Today, the advocates for killing anti-monopoly rules since the Reagan administration insist that deregulation has nothing to do with the rise of monopolies - these monopolies arise out of some mysterious historical force: *when it's monopoly time, you get monopolies.* 21/
This is a wild thing to say aloud among reasonably intelligent adults, like claiming, "Well, when we put out rat poison, we didn't have a rat problem. We stopped, and now we're overrun by rats. 22/
"But it would be hasty to assume that removing the rat poison led to the explosion of rats (by the way, does anyone have a cure for the plague?)" 23/
But if you haven't paid close attention to the history of antitrust law since the late 1970s, all of this might feel mysterious to you - or worse, you might mistake the cause for the effect: regulators keep making corrupt choices, so regulation itself is impossible. 24/
This is like the artists' rights advocate who says, "artists' incomes keep falling, so we need more copyright" - in mistaking the effect for the cause, both blame the system, rather than the corporate power that has corrupted it. 25/
The same is true in our online "censorship" "debate," in which the issue of online speech is "which speech rules should the Big Tech companies that transformed the internet into five giant websites filled with screenshots of the other four adopt?"
Good communities need good rules, sure - but by focusing on *which* rules we have, rather than what keeps people stuck in social media silos that have manifestly *bad* rules, we miss the point. 27/
Absenting yourself from the major social media platforms and online messaging tools extracts major costs on your personal, professional, educational and civil life, so many of us stay within those silos, even though every day we spend there is a torment. 28/
The focus on penalizing firms with bad rules is another one of those mistaking-the-cause-for-the-effect-and-making-it-worse phenomena. 29/
A fine-grained, high-stakes duty to moderate makes it effectively impossible for small platforms - say, community-owned co-ops - to offer an alternative to Big Tech. 30/
And once Big Tech platforms have a duty to police their users, they can argue, reasonably enough, that they can't *also* be forced to interoperate with other platforms whose users they *can't* spy on and thus can't control. 31/
The case that bad community managers give rise to toxic communities breaks down under conditions of monopoly, since attempts to improve platforms with billions of users are: 32/
a) doomed (there is no three-ring binder big enough to encompass all the rules for three billion users); and
b) inimical to standing up smaller, easier-to-administer communities. 33/
Monopoly's singularity also applies to free software and open source. In the mid-1980s, #RichardStallman coined the term #FreeSoftware to apply to software that respected your freedom, specifically, the freedom to inspect, improve and redistribute it. 34/
These were considered the necessary preconditions for freedom in a digital world. Without a guaranteed right to inspect the code that you relied on and correct the defects you found in it, you were a prisoner to the errors or ill intentions of the software's original author. 35/
In 1998, another name was proposed for software licensed on "free" terms: #OpenSource. Nominally, this term was intended to resolve the ambiguity between #FreeAsInBeer and #FreeAsInSpeech - that is, to make it clear that "free software" didn't mean "noncommercial software." 36/
This was said to be necessary to resolve the fears of commercial firms that had been frightened away from free software due to a misunderstanding. 37/
As part of this shift, advocates for "open source" shifted their emphasis from free software's ethical proposition ("software that gives you freedom") to an instrumental narrative. 38/
Open source software was claimed to be *higher quality* than proprietary software, because it hewed to the Enlightenment values of transparency, replicability and peer review ("with enough eyeballs, all bugs are shallow"). 39/
Along with this claim, there was a second argument that open source software was *cheaper* to develop because a "community" would gather to help maintain it. 40/
Sometimes, this was couched as a "commons" where lots of actors, large and small, would work to produce a community good. 41/
In 2018 @makoshark delivered a keynote to the Libreplanet conference that was a kind of postmortem to the 20-year experiment in instrumentalism (open source) over ethics (free software):
42/
Mako concluded that the experiment was a failure, producing a situation in which the tech giants enjoyed unlimited software freedom (because they ran the cloud servers we all depended on). 43/
The rest of us merely had open source (the right to inspect the software powering the cloud, and to suggest ways to modify it). 44/
In this account, the shift from ethics to instrumentalism paved the way for a series of compromises that turned the commons into a sharecropper's precarious farmstead. 45/
When the open community was asked whether cloud software should be subjected to the same #copyleft terms as software distributed for users, they weighed this as an instrumental proposition ("will this make the software better"). 46/
They didn't take it as an ethical one ("will this give users more freedom?") - thus they concluded that the answer was "this is fine."
I think there's a *lot* to this explanation - if nothing else, it explains how such a drastic shift took place without much hue and cry. 47/
But there's another phenomenon at work that Mako's account doesn't grapple with: the rise of tech monopolies.
The reason that ethical propositions related to software freedom were sidelined so effectively in the decades after 1998 is the increasing power of tech monopolies. 48/
As tech giants gobbled up their competitors or put them out of business with predatory pricing, they gained power over regulators, universities, and individual technologists (increasingly employed by or dependent on a tech giant). 49/
Copyleft - like copyright - breaks down at the event horizon of concentrated corporate power. With copyright, the breakdown manifests as the appropriation of copyright's "power to exclude" by the firms it was supposed to be wielded against. 50/
With copyleft, it manifests as "software freedom" being hoarded by the same firms that copyleft licenses were supposed to keep in check.
This isn't limited to free software - it also plagues open-licensed "content" - material released under #CreativeCommons licenses, say. 51/
A year ago, @paul_keller and @atarkowski published an important essay on "openness" entitled "The Paradox of Open":
In this essay, the authors - both significant contributors to the world of free software and open content - identify a phenomenon akin to the Mako's observation of "freedom for big companies, openness for the rest of us." 53/
From Openstreetmap to CC-licensed creative works, corporate monopolies have supercharged their power by plundering the commons.
This month, @OpenFutureEU, who published "Paradox," published a series of responses to the original paper:
Here, Boyle sharply disagrees with Keller and Tarkowski's argument, grouping it with similar claims about content moderation and censorship, arguing that openness was only ever a necessary - but insufficient - precondition for a better world. 56/
In the same way, online speech forums might be terrible places, but this is a failure of their moderators and their communities and their business-models, not an indictment of the idea of online discourse itself. 57/
Both papers grapple with concentrated corporate power as a corrupting force, but neither puts it in the center of the breakdown of otherwise sound practices. 58/
Reading all these people whom I respect and admire so much debating whether "openness" is good or bad makes me even more certain that fighting concentrated corporate power is the precondition for success in *all* other goals. 59/
Fighting concentrated corporate power may seem like a tall order, and it is, but in that fight, we have comfort in a key idea from Boyle's own work. 60/
Boyle describes the history of the term "ecology." Before this term was in widespread use, it wasn't clear when two people were engaged in the same struggle. If you care about endangered owls and I care about the ozone layer, are we on the same team? 61/
What do charismatic nocturnal avians have to do with the gaseous composition of the upper atmosphere?
The term "ecology" turns these issues (and a thousand more) into a *movement*. 62/
Today, there are people of all walks of life living in all kinds of hurt who think their pain is caused by phenomena that are downstream of corporate power. 63/
Once we figure that out - once we figure out that to make our tools work again, we need to escape the event horizon of the capitalist singularity - then we can really begin the fight in earnest. 64/
Image:
NASA's Goddard Space Flight Center (modified)
My publisher @torbooks and @goodreads are drawing for a giveaway of advance copies of my next novel, "Red Team Blues," a Silicon Valley forensic accounting thriller about a cryptocurrency heist - If you're in the US or Canada, enter here to win a copy:
A leak from the @EU_EDPB reveals that the #EU's top #privacy regulator is about to overrule the Irish Data Protection Commission and declare #Facebook's business model illegal, banning #surveillance-based #ads without explicit consent:
If you'd like an essay-formatted version of this thread to read or share, here's a link to it on pluralistic.net, my surveillance-free, ad-free, tracker-free blog:
In some ways, this is unsurprising. Since the #GDPR's beginning, it's been crystal clear that the intention of the landmark privacy regulation was to extinguish commercial surveillance and ring down the curtain on #ConsentTheater. 3/